American Economic Association Where Ricardo and Mill Rebut and Confirm Arguments of Mainstream Economists Supporting Globalization Author(s): Paul A. Samuelson Source: The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 18, No. 3 (Summer, 2004), pp. 135-146 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3216810 . Accessed: 14/04/2011 13:39 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at . http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea. . Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of Economic Perspectives. http://www.jstor.org fournal Ricardo Where Confirm and Arguments Economists Paul 18, Number 3?Summer of Economic Perspectives?Volume Mill Rebut of Mainstream 135-146 and Globalization Supporting A. 2004?Pages Samuelson noneconomists by their are still fearful low when an emerging China and real or India, miracle wage rates, outsourcing cause layoffs from good American jobs. This developments, export-led is a hot issue now, and in the coming decade, it will not go away. enter into the debate to and competent mainstream economists Prominent helped Most educate and correct a fair paraphrase warm-hearted of the protestors who are against globalization. that has been used recently argumentation Greenspan, Jagdish Bhagwati, Gregory Mankiw, Douglas academia. or Jane Doe spread widely throughout Here is by Alan Irwin and economists John Yes, good jobs may be lost here in the short run. But still total U.S. net national product must, by the economic laws of comparative advantage, be raised in the long run (and in China, too). The gains of the winners from free trade, properly measured, work out to exceed the losses of the losers. This is not by mysterious fuzzy magic, but rather comes from a sharing of the trade-induced rise in total global vectors of the goods and services that people in a democ? alongside admitted racy want. Never forget to tally the real gains of consumers in out of what Schumpeter this working possible losses of some producers called "creative capitalist destruction." Correct economic free by dynamic ative" destruction big enough trade. that some American groups can be hurt law recognizes the word "cre? law vindicates But correct economic by its proof [sic] that the gains ofthe the losers. to more than compensate American winners are ? Paul A. Samuelson is Professor of Economics and Institute Professor Emeritus, Massachu? setts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, Massachusetts. 136 fournal of Economic Perspectives The last paragraph can be only an innuendo. For it is dead wrong about I proved in my "Little Nobel Lecture necessary surplus of winnings over losings?as of 1972" (1972b) and elsewhere in references here cited (see also Johnson and and The Stafford, 1993; Gomory Baumol, 2000). present paper provides explication of the popular Here Ricardian untruth. polemical no permanent loss of jobs equilibrium analysis will presuppose either in China or America. Instead, it focuses on the vital question, "Will inventions A or B lower or raise the new market-clearing real wage rates that sustain in both places?" high-to-full employment Act 1(a) of the present paper first rigorously investigates by twenty-first century Ricardo-Mill analysis the following contrived scenario: In the autarky absence of any trade at all, China's precisely measured real income per capita is set at one-tenth of U.S. autarky real income. This for the reason that China's labor productivities are here to out to one-tenth those of the United States. specified average only Quasiis posited here to be ten times that ofthe realistically, China's total labor population United States?so that in autarky any biasing effects of differences in total regional size can be kept out of the analysis. In this example, only a good 1 and a good 2 are assumed to And, a la the young J. S. Mill, demand tastes are everywhere be the same: more precisely, consumers their even-handedly always spend disposable incomes 50-50 on good 1 and on good 2. involved. the initial overall 10-to-l of the United States in absolute superiority that in China's inferiority of produc? 1, productivity, my example stipulates good is much worse than in China's 2 one-tenth; tivity good inferiority vis-a-vis the United States is not as bad as one-tenth. in opinion make for horse-race bets. Differences Despite Differences in relative (!) geographical productivities from specialization and trade. the bounties explain In Act 1(a) 's first part, geographical specialization to happen to double exactly each place's measurable a big brownie point for the economist debaters. between good 1 and good 2 Vive les differencesl and fair free trade are shown autarky real income. So far, Act 1(b) goes on to address how the United States and China will fare when technical in China has quadrupled her labor's pro? Schumpeterian improvement to the United ductivity in good 2, which is the good that China has been exporting States. below In my stipulated that of the United far below the United China's average productivity still remains far example, States. But, remember that so too are China's real wages States'. In a nutshell, the new fair trade equilibrium must definitely create for the States a better real net national product?better because we can buy our does also in my Millimports cheaper now. China's good 2 elevated productivity Ricardo scenario raise her real net national product; and it happens to do so equally United with the United States?even some? though China's terms of trade do deteriorate to lower China's per capita net national product when what, albeit not enough demand elasticity is Mill-like. Acts 1(a) and 1(b)'s valid numerical deductions are debaters. pluses for the economist proglobalization Act II, however, deals some weighty blows against economists' oversimple Paul A. Samuelson 137 about globalization. It shifts focus to a new and different kind of complacencies In Act II, China's progress takes place (by imitation Chinese technical innovation. or home ingenuity or . . . ) in good 1, in which the United States has previously had a comparative advantage. (High I.Q. secondary school graduates in South Dakota, who had been receiving from my New York Bank wages one-and-a-half times the U.S. minimum wage for handling phone calls about my credit card, have been laid off since Bombay exceeds unit has come to handle my inquiries. Their 1990; a Bombay outsourcing rate falls far of short South Dakota's, but in India their wage far wage what their uncles and aunts used to earn.) What does Ricardo-Mill arith? tell us about In Act II, effects from such outsourcings? this that invention abroad that, productivities imply gives to China some of the comparative had that to the United States advantage belonged can induce for the United States permanent lost per capita real income?an Act II metic realistic U.S. long-run the new Ricardian loss even equal to all of Act 1(a)'s 100 percent gain over autarky. And, mind well, this would not be a short run impact effect. Ceteris paribus it can be a permanent hurt. means for as long as the postinvention still apply.) ("Permanent" technologies In Ricardian equilibrium analysis, there is never any longest run unemploy? So it is not that U.S. jobs are ever lost in the long run; it is that the new labor-market clearing real wage has been lowered by this version of dynamic fair free trade. (Does Act II forget about how the United States benefits from cheaper ment. imports? No. There are no such neat net benefits, but rather there are now new net harmful U.S. terms of trade.) on the robustness and relevance of the will comment Finally, the Epilogue spelled out analyses in the two Acts. Qualitatively most part remain relevant. my Ricardian Act Nations9 1(a): Incomes How Free Compared Trade Benefits Both theorems Real Per do for the Capita to Autarky law. Here we begin with Analytical proof trumps mere talk about economic China possessed of average productivity a tenth of the U.S. level. To remove only in differences the two total and labor force, China's complicating outputs places' workforce is set at ten times that of the United States: say that the total U.S. is 100, while China's total workforce is 1,000. Ricardian productivity are exogenously given in my initial parameters scenarios. For the the are United labor States, two-good respective productivities = 2 and = -; for China = ? and ? 77 are Hl 7^ II2 tt2 they (Notationally, capital workforce Four letters observe denote U.S. variables; that U.S. lower case denote out Chinese to ten times variables.) China's. Readers will But the U.S. productivities average superiority is more than ten in good 1; and China's inferiority in good 2 is not as bad as one-tenth. is Before any trade, China's autarky per capita real income contrived to work out to precisely one-tenth of U.S. autarky per capita real income; 138 fournal before States. of Economic Perspectives trade, good 2 is relatively Here are the details. cheap in China while good Autarky's "Before" Equilibrium In autarky, if the United States devotes 1 is cheap in the United to good 1, it can to produce good 2, it can workers: 500 produce for China's 1,000 produce 100 of good 2. Because people all only 25 of good 2; and the other 500 produce 50-50 their incomes on the two will assume that, in spend goods, competition a quantity of 100; if it devotes holds 25. A parallel calculation 50 of its 100 workers the other 50 workers autarky, each place must allocate its labor supply 50-50 between goods 1 and 2. In this autarky example, the opportunity a unit of good 2 in cost of producing the United States is 4 units of good 1. However, in China, the opportunity cost of in a of is unit of 1. These differences relative unit producing good 2 good and in autarky geographic productivities price ratios provide the basis for com? parative advantage-induced geographical specialization that will amplify world productivity! tactical advance over nineteenth-century Ricardo-Mill is My twenty-first-century to recognize that Mill's assumption of 50-50 expenditures on the two goods gives us a firm measuring rod for an exact index of real national incomes and for real world is the geometric mean of consumption.1 Thus, in the United income can be as mean of producing real measured the States, autarky geometric 100 of good 1 and 25 of good 2, which is the square root of 100 multiplied by the root or 50. the assumed U.S. of U.S. of 25, 100, square Dividing by population per income. This index capita real income will then be 0.5. In China, autarky real income is the geometric mean of producing 25 of good 1 and 100 of good 2, which is the square root of 25 of the multiplied by square root of 100, or also 50. Dividing by China's population 1,000, we calculate per capita autarky real income in China as 0.05. is a second, these various real national equivalent way of measuring It is useful because it involves the mean, not of geometric outputs. especially or consumed, but of the real wage rates of the two goods in each quantities produced In the U.S. real place. autarky, wage rates are respectively precisely, for W/Px and = 2 and = - Ricardian U.S. the real per capita autarky Yil W/P2, II2 productivities. in the previous paragraph is (for Mill) also given by the income of 0.5 as computed There duality China, = = Likewise, for \V(W/P1)(W/P2) \Vn^2 \ J^\. its real net national product per capita of 0.05 is given also by - VTiyn^ = ? formula: 0.5 20 10 2V10; The above exact = equality of U.S. and Chinese total outputs results only from 1 The use of the geometric mean and the harmonic mean as money-metric utilities, and how they can be derived from indifference curves, is explained in Appendix 2, which is appended to the paper at the journal's website (http://www.ejep.org). Where Ricardo and Mill Rebut and Confirm Arguments my contrived simplifying example. We now replace autarky by free trade, a substantial gain in real per capita welfare in both places. deducing 139 thereby Free Trade's "After" Equilibrium The present model puts capital movements at zero. In free trade equilibrium, the trade balance is here always zero. With no tariffs, quotas or transport costs, in free trade relative price ratios will end up everywhere Of course, real equalized. wage rates will still diverge after free trade has raised them in both places. The first step in analyzing free trade is to deduce the qualitative pattern of Because the opportunity cost of producing in specialization. good 1, expressed terms of good 2, is lower in the United States, competition will impel the United States to specialize on good 1. Because the opportunity cost of producing good 2, in terms of good 1, is lower in China, China's competitors will specialize expressed on good 2. Indeed, avaricious U.S. Darwinian on will concentrate competition level of 2 will good 1 only; so that its 100 workers with a productivity produce 200 of good 2. China's comparative advantage will impel her competitors to produce workers with productivity of good 2 only, and the 1,000 Chinese two-tenths will produce 200 units of good 2. This free trade geographical special? producing ization can thus vastly raise world income as compared to autarky. Each good's autarky global outputs of 125 are raised 60 percent by free trade's specializations. Each place imports some of the good it does not produce, and does so at the market that equate The combi? supply and demand. nation which use the regions' respective labors to specializations, what can produce only they produce relatively (!) best, and then trade, does iron out the huge autarky price ratio divergences. about income being evenly divided in both countries Using Mill's assumption clearing prices of geographical international between both goods, and the fact that global production with specialization will = a of for both then the free trade 200 ratio, equal quantity goods, P2/Pi price in both frictionless auctioneer becomes p2/p!, equalized places by exchange, or 1. At this balanced artifact 200/200 (which is a contrived price configuration from my example's whose purpose was to simplify read? cunning skew symmetries ers' quick understanding), it is self-evident that both nations will share equally (not in world total real outputs. When each country per capita equally) half-and-half consumes 100 geometric tries, each mean of each necessarily be equal.) realistic asymmetries of the 200 world outputs?their free trade good?half will be twice their autarky geometric mean. (Without my symme? place's relative gain over autarky will still be positive but will not Many in this benefits Most could the exact equality negate is the counterintuitive important of percentage truth that a example. of China's population relative to the United States will raise China's per real income at the of lowering the U.S. gain from free trade! capita expense Noneconomists and Marxian economists but that is their 180? guess otherwise, reduction wrong error. 140 Act fournal When 1(b): Raise Must of Economic Perspectives China's U.S. Per Technical Capita in Its Progress Real But Income, Sector Export When It Might Lower China's has China exogenously a quadruexperiencing 9 of 7r2 = ? sector: that is, the initial productivity = All other productivities remain the tt2> y^. Here our thought experiment in her export of pling productivity in good 2 becomes postinvention same. Both before invention and after, the Ricardian of comparative inequalities to to the United States specialize only on good 1 and advantage compel China to specialize only on good 2. When all 100 U.S. workers produce good 1, they still produce a total of 200 only; when all 100 Chinese workers produce good 2, with 800. World output is clearly the higher level, they now produce productivity continue in China's productivity. by this improvement United States the garners some part of the world gain in measured net Always of China's q2 relative to global product. Why? Because the new superabundance U.S. Qx necessarily lowers P2/Pi to us as consumers. unchanged increased Millian demand, China also gains in measurable well being. Suppose, in Mill's demand than that demands are much more inelastic however, empirically structure. Then the quadrupled supply of China's good 2 output could so much lower China's export terms of trade p2/pi as to plunge postinvention per capita Under income share China's (Postinvention, per capita income. all the down to only one-fifth, no way drops Self-immiseration phenom? by a nation is a well-known painfully below preinvention of world net national product longer staying at one-half.) enon in the economic literature, and it does up here crop in the debate over globalization.2 Act II: Proof Loss in Per Productivity Production that Capita Gain of the United Real States Income in Good When 1 Large Permanent Suffers China Enough to Measurable Enjoys Exogenous Cut Some U.S. It By contrast with Act I's proof of U.S. benefit from Chinese technical progress in her export sector, Act II's analysis will rebut any mainstream economist's claims abroad in a that the United States cannot suffer tong-term harm from innovation world of free trade. I begin 2 In with the same initial two-good Ricardian productivities as in Act I. concluding Act I's brief in favor of globalization, I remind readers of my Appendix 2's discussion of how replacing Mill demand by realistic inelastic demand will actually cause China to be hurt by her own invention. Appendix 2, which offers detailed proofs, is appended to this article at the journal website (http://www.ejep.org). 141 Paul A. Samuelson 112 = ? = -; and 7r2 = ?. But now, for dramatic the invention, ni =2 and II2 ttx in good 1 mightily, from 7rx = ? to I expand China's labor productivity emphasis, = remain unchanged. (Note: Despite the great ttv jr-. The rest ofthe productivities for good 1 to above the U.S. level of labor increase in China's labor productivity for good 1, China still remains poorer in autarky than the United productivity Before still with a lower average real wage.) the invention, just as in Act I, the United States produces only 200 units of good 1, while China produces only 200 units of good 2. But now, after the has markedly grown. However, all comparative world output potential invention, the reason that now, in every place, Ilj/r^ emasculated?for have been advantages States?and Before and ttx/tt2 both now equal 4. Each place can do as well in its new autarky as it can do under free trade. (Indeed under free trade rules, no one is any longer motivated there is no need or advantage in doing either exportto specialize geographically; whole story can be easily told. To appraise U.S. or So this example's ing importing.) well being, ignore Ricardo postinvention States' postinvention autarky geometric mean. geometric and Mill; just simply compare mean with its preinvention the United trade free free trade elicited 200 of good 1 from the that the preinvention numbers 200 of good 2 from China. Also, these balanced = that both a nice balance meant of Such mandated places (P^Pj)' unity. (p2/pi)' mean as measured with the geometric shared one-half of world national income, V200 ? 200 = 200. Focusing on U.S. per capita welfare, that meant preinvention = 1.0. free trade per capita net national product had been - (200)/100 Query: Can We've United seen States and mean ever reattain that earlier U.S. autarky per capita geometric postinvention the level? The answer is a surprising "no." Forced into autarky by China's invention, in our crucial thought experiment United States with its unchanging technology goods 1 and 2. Producing again divides its 100 workers evenly between producing 50 ? 2 = 100 of good 1, and 50 ? | = 25 of good 2, then U.S. real per capita income = 0.5. = 50/100 mean as VlOO ? 25/100 can be measured by the geometric Assuredly that does fall short of her initial per capita national income with free trade, which was 1.0. The new winds in my overdramatic they example, from free trade. previous enjoyments of free trade have blown have blown well for China. all of the United But States' away (Test question: Could there be any pattern of reduce absolutely future inventions abroad that would repeatedly per capita U.S. Correct answer: Yes?however benefits from free trade and globalization? unlikely pattern would be.) One example can sometimes that dramatic own spontaneous killing be "too clever by half." In this one it is free trade's off of all trade that does harm to the United States.5 3 To avoid breeding misunderstanding, my Appendix 1, which is appended to this article at the journal's website (http://www.ejep.org), analyzes a more realistic three-good scenario. Add to goods 1 and 2, with their original productivities in the two countries, a good 3, which begins with n3 = 1 and irs = ?. The example therefore happens to force initial equal sharing by both places of world total output of good 3: that is, shared comparative advantages. Then, exogenously, let China's productivity in good 3 double 142 fournal of Economic Perspectives numerical results are not mere numbers drawn from a my reported black box. In every case, it is terms of trade changes in (Pg/P^ W/P1? in those variables mandated by exogenous W/P2; w/p! ,w/p2)?changes changes in relative scarcities?that have had their intuitively effects on expected supplyAgain mysterious demand free trade. equilibrium price ratios under competitive Economic first insidiously and later history is replete with Act II examples, in the United moved from east to west two centuries States, decisively: farming ago; moved from New England to the low-wage South textiles, shoes and manufacturers became replaced by early in the last century; Victorian manufacturing hegemony Yankee inroads after 1850. Even where the leaders continued in to progress absolute growth, their rate of growth tended often to be attenuated an adverse by headwind generated from low-wage competitors and technical imitators. Epilogue Acts I and II have demonstrated that sometimes free trade globalization can change abroad into a benefit for both regions; but sometimes a productivity gain in one country can benefit that country alone, while perma? nently hurting the other country by reducing the gains from trade that are possible between the two countries.4 All of this constitutes effects, long-run Schumpeterian quite aside from and different from transitory short-run harms traceable to shortconvert a technical run adjustment costs or to temporary on nopolies knowledge. rents from patents and from eroding mo? It does not follow from my corrections and emendations that nations should or not introduce selective protectionisms. Even where a genuine harm is dealt out by the roulette wheel of evolving comparative in a world of free advantage should trade, what a democracy tries to do in self defense may often amount to gratuitously itself in the foot. A pragmatic and scientifically more correct brief for shooting globalization might go as follows. If the past and the future bring both Type A inventions and Type B inventions that help?and when both that hurt your country add to world real net to 7r3,= ? >which isjust enough to kill off a/ZU.S. production of good 3. Does that hurt us permanendy ceterisparibus net? Yes, indeed it does. But this time the hurt to us comes from an increasein foreign trade?from initial zero trade in good 3, all of U.S. consumption of good 3 comes after China's irs invention from imports alone. 4 Some past scholars have wondered whether cheapening of transport costs and speedier spreading of knowledge across national boundaries might in the future decimate comparative advantages and foreign trade. They have also wondered whether, when all peoples are as productive as Americans, some of their new benefit might come out of reduced U.S. well-being. So far, economic history has reported gain rather than loss in the ratio between Total Foreign Trade + Total World Output. If trade were ever to cease spontaneously under competition, since shipping goods back and forth for no good reason makes no sense, humanity ought to deem such a result to be good rather than bad, even if it exacts some price from the erstwhile most productive geographical place. 143 Where Ricardo and Mill Rebut and Confirm Arguments national to be free trade may turn out pragmatically product welfare?then tariffs and for each region in comparison with lobbyist-induced and nonsubtle dead? of democracy which involve both perversion "Tariffs are the distortion losses. In 1900 free traders proclaimed, still best quotas weight Mother of trusts." In this millennium are the breeder A few words a more truth may be: "Tariffs pregnant arteriosclerosis." of economic to judge are needed robust how my simplified Ricardo-Mill paradigm is to real-world complexities. to international 1. Adding nontradable goods or other realistic impediments not fundamental reflection deduces will findings. negate my exchange, analytic to Ricardo's also remain valid after adding conclusions 2. My qualitative the post-1930 by Heckmultifactor trade models pioneered labor-only technologies McKenzie, Jones and Lerner, Stolper-Samuelson, scher, Ohlin, Viner, Haberler, others, to say nothing of earlier Marshall and Edgeworth multifactor trade models. the Dornbusch-Fischer-Samuelson (1980) nicely generalized Just as multifactor Dornbusch-Fischer-Samuelson found that the qualitative to labor-only scenarios. so will it be (1977) Ricardian labor-only paradigm, as results of Acts I and II do apply as well to multifactor 3. In this paper, along classical lines, all my free trade equilibria are analyzed the assumptions of zero net capital movements. In this epoch of chronic longsuch simple Ricardo-Mill smacks of U.S. net foreign indebtedness, term cumulative Buffett?the Noneconomists like Warren the Gloomy Dane. Hamlet without under and most richest world's blamed successful the chronic is one?in investor deficit (2003) Fortune on free trade and paper to do November U.S. international payments zero U.S. borrowing-andauction taxes that would enforce proposed could deduce the measurable This net. self-imposed lending paper's techniques But harm America would bring down on itself by following the Buffett philosophy. magazine therefore one-way U.S. justice. 4. What balance-of-payment deficits need another that topic in a two-country, model can be shown to two- or three-good in an Ricardo-Mill A^country, M-good paradigm. essentially based squarely on the trade paradigms 5. Smith-Allyn Young-Ohlin-Krugman returns to scale technol? from of increasing inseparable imperfections competition holds hold Ricardianisms. However, by classical competitive analyzed (2000) have reported findings similar to mine for various increas? Gomory-Baumol enlargeing returns to scale scenarios. I should add that it has been globalization's model to greater ment of market size that has done much to elevate the competitive ogies are not well in the 1890-1950 model possessed than the competitive epoch. policy relevance 6. My most important omission, for realism and for policy, is treating all people our That inhibits laborers. in each region as different homogeneous Ricardian grappling with the realistic computer experts) cases where may be being helped and skilled (capitalists the real free-trade by what is decimating some Americans 144 of Economic Perspectives fournal or of the blue-collar wage rates of the semi-skilled factory workers. My geometric mean approach can fortunately be adapted to handle just such problems. Instead of attenuating this paper's theses, heterogeneity amplifies its impor? tance. a scenario where Schumpeter's fruitful capitalist destruction Contemplate harms a really sizeable fraction of the future U.S. population and, say, improves welfare of another group and does that so much as to justify a calculation that the winners could be made to transfer some of their gains and thereby leave no U.S. group net losers from free trade. Should noneconomists accept this as cogent rebuttal if there is no evidence that compensating fiscal transfers have been made or will be made? Marie Antoinette said, "Let them eat cake." But history substantial records no transfer sometimes Greenspan 1930s?Hicks, of sugar and flour to her peasant subjects. sounds Antoinette-ish. The economists' Even the sage Dr. literature of the of earlier Lerner, Kaldor, Scitovsky and others, to say nothing Pareto and ofa shell Mill, writings byJ.S. Edgeworth, Viner?perpetrates something in ethical debates about the conflict between and game efficiency greater inequality. aside and ethical trade economists have aside, mainstream judgments the in drastic in mean U.S. incomes and insufficiently change inequalities among different U.S. classes. As in any other society, perhaps a third of Americans are not highly educated and not energetic enough to qualify for skilled professional Policy noticed into the United States of similar workers to jobs. If mass immigration been permitted to actually take place, mainstream economists could a substantial in of this native while the predicting drop wages group rise over what their old-country real grants were earning a substantial them not had avoid new immi? wages had been. as a result of my 1948-1949 revival and perfecting of the 1919Therefore, 1933 Heckscher-Ohlin of argumentation factorprice quasi-equalization by trade in goods the following at World War IFs end. Historically, alone, one could have foreseen U.S. workers and used to have know-hows kind of a de facto monopoly access to the superlative and of the United (scientific, engineering managerial) so to speak, were born with silver spoons in our mouths ? capitals States. All of us Yankees, and that importantly explained the historically high U.S. market-clearing real wage house small business owners and so others) (among janitors, helpers, forth. However, after World War II, this U.S. know-how and capital began to spread rates for faster away from the United States. That meant that in a real sense foreign in western Europe, then throughout masses?first the Pacific Rim?could the same of competitive pressures on U.S. lower that mass migration would have threatened to do. genuinely provide class wage earnings Post-2000 outsourcing as 1950. future And in accordance 2004-2050 kind Japan in temporary chaos) and did middle is just what ought to have been predictable as far back with basic economic law, this will only grow in the Other authors could add, to my presented Acts I and II, there took a in historical the U.S. share why place drop period. Acts explaining of total global output from almost additional educable 50 percent at 1945 war's end (with Europe and down to 40 percent, down to 30 percent and, according Paul A. Samuelson to the Penn World Tables of purchasing-power-corrected per capita these trends down to perhaps only one-fifth to one-quarter. Although an absolute decline in U.S. affluence, they arguably did reflect a head rate of real growth in the last half of down the U.S. post-Keynes 145 now incomes, did not mean wind slowing the twentieth century. as Japan, Hong Kong, Not surprisingly, successful nations?such developing and the Philippines? Indonesia South even Taiwan, Thailand, Korea, Singapore, lead over their were able at the end of the twentieth century to reduce America's for western Europe in the own per capita real incomes. The same thing happened 1950-1980 whether one or more of these trailing bicycle period. One wondered riders would fully catch up with the U.S. bicycle and then maybe even forge ahead of it. The Penn World Tables and Angus Maddison's similar estimates seem not to as yet. Could that be a sign that the United States' original report that happening as they spread abroad, have been the important factors in explaining innovations, America's diminishing lead? One hesitates to say. Actually there is some suggestive evidence that French or If only German per-hour productivity does surpass the U.S. per-hour productivity. the French and Germans would match U.S. weekly and monthly average number of total hours of work, their bicycles would be running ahead ofthe U.S. frontrunner. in Ricardo-like tastes can modify technological Evidently subjective parameters economics. explaining global and domestic dynamic patterns of contemporary more are exaggerated, Even if my hypotheses they are what both Ricardo models seem to be suggesting. would general Ricardo-Mill and References Bhagwati, Jagdish. 2004. "WhyYour Job isn't Moving to Bangalore." New YorkTimes.January 22, Op-ed. Buffett, Warren. 2003. "Warren Buffett: Why I'm Down on the Dollar." Fortune.November 10, 148:1, pp. 106-16. Diewert, W. E. and A. Nakamura, eds. 1993. Essays in Index Number Theory.Amsterdam and New York: North-Holland. Dornbusch, Rudiger, Stanley Fischer and Paul A. Samuelson. 1977. "Comparative Advantage, Trade, and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods." AmericanEconomicRe? view. December, 67, pp. 823-39. Reproduced in The CollectedScientificPapersofPaul A. Samuelson, Volume5. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1986, chapter 316. Dornbusch, Rudiger, Stanley Fischer and Paul A. Samuelson. 1980. "Heckscher-Ohlin Trade Theory with a Continuum of Goods." Quarterly Journal of Economics.September, 95, pp. 203-24. Reproduced in The CollectedScientificPapers of Paul A. Samuelson, Volume5. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press, 1986, chapter 317. Gomory, Ralph E. and William J. Baumol. 2000. GlobalTrade and ConflictingNational Inter? ests. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Irwin, Douglas. 2004. "'Outsourcing' is Good for America." New YorkTimes.January 28, Op-ed. Johnson, George E. and Frank P. Stafford. 1993. "International Competition and Real Wages." American Economic Review. May, 82, pp. 127-30. Kravis, Irving, Alan Heston and Robert 146 fournal of Economic Perspectives Summers. 1978. InternationalComparisonsof Real Productand PurchasingPower.Baltimore and Lon? don: Johns Hopkins University Press for the World Bank. Kuznets, Simon. 1946. National Income:A Sum? maryof Findings. New York: NBER. Mill, John S. 1844. Essays on Some Unsettled Questionsof PoliticalEconomy.London: Parker. Ohlin. Bertil. 1933. Interregionaland Interna? tional Trade.Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Univer? sity Press. Ricardo, David. 1817. On thePrincipleof Politi? cal Economyand Taxation.London: John Murray, 1821. Volume 1 in P. Sraffa, ed., with the assis? tance of M. H. Dobb, The Worksand Correspon? denceof David Ricardo.Cambridge: University of Cambridge Press, 1953. Samuelson, Paul A. 1948. "International Trade and Equalisation of Factor Prices." Eco? nomicJournal.June, 58, pp. 163-84. Reproduced in The CollectedScientificPapersofPaul A. Samuel? son, Volume 2. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1977, chapter 67. Samuelson, Paul A. 1949. "International Factor-Price Equalisation Once Again." Economic Journal.June, 59, pp. 181-97. Reproduced in The CollectedScientificPapersofPaul A. Samuelson,Vol? ume2. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1977, chap? ter 68. Samuelson, Paul A. 1972a. "Heretical Doubts About the International Mechanism." Journal of InternationalEconomics.September, 2, pp. 44354. Reproduced in The CollectedScientificPapersof PaulA. Samuelson,Vol. 4. Cambridge, Mass.:MIT Press, 1977, chapter 256. Samuelson, Paul A. 1972b. "International Trade for a Rich Country." Lectures before the Swedish-American Chamber of Commerce, New York City, May 10. Stockholm: Federation of Swedish Industries. Reproduced in The Collected ScientificPapers of Paul A. Samuelson, Volume4. Cambridge, Mass.:MIT Press, 1977, chapter 250. Samuelson, Paul A. 1974. "Complementarity: An Essay on the 40th Anniversary of the HicksAllen Revolution in Demand Theory."Journal of EconomicLiterature.December, 12, pp. 1255-289. Reproduced in The CollectedScientificPapers of Paul A. Samuelson,Volume4. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1977, chapter 208. Samuelson, Paul A. 1981. "To Protect Manu? facturing?" Zeitschriftfiir die gesamteStaatswissenschaft (Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics).September, 137, pp. 407-14. Repro? duced in The CollectedScientificPapers of Paul A. Samuelson, Volume 5. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1986, chapter 324. Samuelson, Paul A. and S. Swamy. 1973. "Invariant Economic Index Numbers and Canoni? cal Duality: Survey and Synthesis." AmericanEco? nomic Review. August, 64, pp. 566-93. Reproduced in The CollectedScientificPapers of Paul A. Samuelson,Volume4. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1977, chapter 209. Schumpeter, Joseph. 1942. Capitalism,Socialism and Democracy. New York:Harper & Brothers.
© Copyright 2024