Guns, butter and debt: Sovereign creditworthiness and military expenditure Matthew DiGiuseppe Department of Political Science University of Mississippi mrdigius@olemiss.edu Abstract I argue that favorable access to sovereign credit provides governments with greater autonomy to invest in security by allowing political incumbents to relax fixed-budget constraints. Borrowing permits leaders to delay and minimize the macroeconomic and redistributive costs associated with domestic sources of finance. Consequently, leaders of creditworthy states face fewer political costs when increasing military expenditure in response to growing demand or maintaining military expenditure when government revenues fall. A cross-sectional time-series analysis supports two observable implications of the argument. First, creditworthiness is positively associated with military spending with an effect on par with regime type. Second, creditworthiness conditions the effect of external threats on military expenditure suggesting that poor credit terms constrain the provision of security. Forthcoming in the Journal of Peace Research Keywords: Military Spending, International Security, International Finance, Sovereign Credit, Sovereign Debt. The ‘Great Recession’ has demonstrated the manner in which national security is vulnerable to global economic forces. Governments once privileged with consistent sovereign credit access have faced serious credit constraints and mounting debt burdens. Consequently, those states hardest hit by the crisis have cut military budgets, while those that maintained favorable credit terms saw little reductions in spending (SIPRI, 2010, 177-78). Even in the United States, which has retained consistent access to credit, policymakers have expressed concerns that debt burdens and fiscal constraints resulting from a lack of credit may eventually constrain security policy. Former Secretary of State Hillary Clinton expressed that ‘[debt] undermines our capacity to act in our own interests, and it does constrain us where constraint may be undesirable (Lander, 2010)’ and former Chairman of the Joint Chiefs of Staff Admiral Mike Mullen has remarked that the ‘biggest threat to our national security is our debt (Sanger, 2013).’ Are the these concerns valid? Previous research has demonstrated that military expenditures have a significant impact on national debt burdens (Brzoska, 1983, Looney & Frederiksen, 1986, Dunne & Smith, 2007, Smyth & Narayan, 2009, Heo & Bohte, 2012). This indicates that many states do incur debt burdens to finance security. However, less research directly addresses concerns that a government’s credit access and borrowing costs constrain security.1 Research thus far has largely considered the impact of a state’s credit terms on material and political constraints within the context of major power war, rivalry, and other conflict outcomes (Rasler & Thompson, 1983, Schultz & Weingast, 2003, Slantchev, 2012, Shea, 2014, Flores & Kreps, 2013, DiGiuseppe, forthcoming, Poast, 2015). This article builds on this growing literature by demonstrating a broader relationship between sovereign creditworthiness and security funding. I argue that the leaders of creditworthy states can minimize or delay the political costs imposed by the alternatives to borrowing and thus have greater autonomy to increase and maintain military expenditure. I test two observable implications of the argument with the 1 Debt burdens are driven by both new debt and accumulated interest on old debts. 1 first cross-sectional time-series analysis of a relationship between sovereign creditworthiness and defense spending. First, I present strong evidence that sovereign creditworthiness is associated with higher military expenditure. Second, I also demonstrate that sovereign credit has strategic implications by demonstrating that the growing power of rivals is associated with an increase in military spending in creditworthy states but has no impact on the spending of credit poor states. The argument and analysis have important implications for several areas of academic research and policy. First, the article demonstrates that a state’s access to credit has a broad influence on security beyond conflict outcomes. Second, the article furthers understanding of the determinants of military spending by identifying a variable with an effect on par with regime type. In doing so, it also adds to the growing understanding that international political economy, and more specifically international finance, are closely tied to international security. Next, the theory and findings question the viability of the assumption, common the both analyses of spending priorities and many prominent theoretical models of world politics, that all governments face fixed-budget constraints. The findings also support the contention that the politics of domestic redistribution have significant consequences for the strategic security interactions between states. Lastly, the empirical analysis has clear policy relevance that is reflected by recent turbulence in international credit markets that has threatened the ability of both industrialized and emerging market governments to sustain military spending after the ‘Great Recession.’ Credit and war The notion that states use borrowed capital to fund security is not new. Economic history demonstrates that major powers that held the confidence of international investors have consistently borrowed to outspend credit poor and fiscally troubled adversaries and rivals (Kennedy, 1988, Brewer, 1990, Bordo & White, 1991, Ferguson, 2001). States restricted from 2 foreign capital were limited to funds available through domestic extraction and eventually scaled back military output or suffered economically from unsuccessful efforts to raise capital through distortionary fiscal or monetary policies. Furthermore, the use of credit promoted long-run economic growth and power as governments avoided distortionary fluctuations and decreased economic uncertainty by using borrowed funds to smooth over gaps in revenue and taxes (Barro, 1979). This focus on the material advantages of credit within major power rivalry and war is also found in world politics literature. Rasler and Thompson (1983) propose that great powers partially owe their ascension to the ‘ability to obtain credit inexpensively, to sustain relatively large debts, and in general to leverage the initially limited base of their wealth in order to meet their staggering military expenses (490).’ The losers of hegemonic contests, they contend, failed to ‘maintain a sufficiently competitive financial capability’ often despite an advantage in traditional sources of capital. Schultz and Weingast (1998, 2003) add that the advantage democratic and limited governments hold in raising foreign capital helps explain their success in war fighting and overcoming rivals. The arguments connecting a state’s credit terms to its material capacity are well suited to explain outcomes where states approach the limits of their capacity to extract domestic resources, such as total war. However, states rarely approach this constraint. Under most circumstances, the political consequences of extracting resources from society prevents incumbents from reaching these limits. Appreciating the political interests and constraints of the actors actually making budgetary decisions sheds light on credit’s broader influence on security. For example, Shea (2014) argues that democratic governments are more sensitive to war’s economic costs and thus the ability to minimize tax burdens through borrowing exerts a larger influence on the probability that democratic states, relative to non-democratic states, win wars. DiGiuseppe (forthcoming) goes further and suggests that the macroeconomic and sub-national distributional consequences of non-credit financing have implications for the survival of all leaders that are dependent on a competitive distribution of public and 3 private goods to retain office. His evidence suggests that beyond war outcomes, a state’s creditworthiness, by facilitating affordable borrowing, shields leaders from the current and potential costs of conflict giving them a freer hand to initiate interstate conflict. Recent research also supports the notion that the political consequences of taxes and other nonborrowing tools to finance conflict influence politicians’ behavior. Flores & Kreps (2013) present evidence that United States politicians who represented those likely to be saddled with war taxes had a greater propensity to favor alternative methods of war finance. While recent studies show that the political benefits of creditworthiness influence conflictrelated outcomes, the arguments have broader implications.2 A state’s ability to respond to internal and external demands and maintain security commitments in peace time are crucial for deterring threats. In fact, recent research finds losing credit access increases the probability a government forms an alliance (Allen & DiGiuseppe, 2013). The evidence is consistent with the notion that states see alliance power as a substitute for arms when the costs of armaments to deter or fight a war require unpopular fiscal policies. In all, research demonstrating credit’s influence on a number of discrete foreign policy outcomes is suggestive of a broader relationship linking the political economy of security with a state’s ability to raise material resources. As such, evidence that credit financing has a broader impact on the political economy of security should be apparent in a state’s military expenditure. Creditworthiness and military spending Defense spending is often the costliest component of a state’s foreign policy apparatus and provides a significant amount of information about a state’s position in the world. As such, understanding what accounts for variation in military spending has numerous implications for the study of world politics and foreign policy. For practical purposes, military expenditure provides greater variance upon which to examine the relationship between credit and security 2 In fact, the arguments center around a government’s ability to finance militaries but lack a direct test of the mechanism. 4 than available in the discrete outcomes previously explored in the literature. Economic models of defense spending have generally assumed rational welfare maximizing agents make decisions over military spending under fixed budget constraints (Smith, 1995). From this perspective, the primary determinants of military expenditures are external threats, demographics and government resources (Dunne & Smith, 2007, Collier & Hoeffler, 2007, Nordhaus et al., 2012). Other arguments and models from a variety of disciplines relax the assumptions of a welfare maximizing agent. To varying degrees, this research considers the incentives facing policy makers and find that sub-national factors relating to political institutions offer substantial purchase in explaining variation in military expenditure (Garfinkel, 1994, Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2004, Goldsmith, 2007, Albalate et al., 2012, Conrad et al., 2013, Carter & Palmer, forthcoming). Yet, researchers commonly assume that fixed budgets constrain decision makers and that institutions influence the relative value of guns and butter. This assumption persists despite growing evidence that, at least among industrialized states, many governments pursue both guns and butter (Domke et al., 1983, Mintz, 1989, Whitten & Williams, 2011). Furthermore, little research addresses the variety of fiscal tools used to finance defense spending in an attempt to understand how states can avoid trade-offs (Heo & Bohte, 2012). The literature mentioned in the previous section provides strong reasons to believe that the fiscal tools available to incumbents, notably the cost of borrowing, strongly influence their ability to provide security while avoiding direct costs on society (Shea, 2014, DiGiuseppe, forthcoming, Flores & Kreps, 2013). The idea that borrowing is politically efficient and obfuscates the true cost of expenditure has a long history in political economy (Hume, 1970 1752, Smith, 1776, Mill, 1984 1994, Kant, 1795 2003). However, modern economics literature largely rejects this notion as it is in conflict with the assumption of perfectly informed self-interested rational individuals and the assumption that governments are benevolent social planners. The concept of ‘Ricardian Equivalence’ claims that fully informed rational taxpayers recognize that there is no ‘free lunch’ and that future taxes are required to repay debts (Barro, 1974). If this proposition 5 reflects real life, then those bearing the burden of security spending have little reason to prefer borrowing over taxes and may even punish incumbents for the additional burden of interest payments. However, the theorem relies on strong assumptions that even Ricardo doubted existed in practice (Dooley, 1989). Furthermore, the theorem lacks direct empirical support (Seater, 1993, Ricciuti & DiLaurea, 2003, Banzhaf & Oates, 2013) and is at odds with evidence that that individuals hold inconsistent preferences (i.e. wanting both lower taxes and higher spending) or simply misperceive the costs and benefits of public services due the complexity of tax systems (Citrin, 1979, Wagner, 1976). If individuals discount the future or are not fully informed about fiscal policy, survival minded incumbents have a strong motivation to incur debt to maintain their grip on power by minimizing the current burden imposed on relevant constituents. This behavior is consistent with some recent research. Empirical evidence does suggest that leaders do ‘buy off potential rivals and reward supporters’ by borrowing foreign capital (Easterly, 2002, 1680). Thomas Oatley finds that debt burdens are in fact correlated with the discount rate of different political regimes (2010). Further, DiGiuseppe et al. (2012) find that sovereign creditworthiness decreases the probability of rebellion and DiGiuseppe & Shea (forthcoming) find that increases in borrowing costs and credit downgrades shorten leader tenure. If borrowing is politically beneficial, it is not difficult to see how creditworthiness can influence military expenditure. As is common in political economy models of foreign policy, I assume that the desire to remain in power motivates leaders and constituents hold leaders accountable to their provision of both security and the distribution of public and private goods (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003). As demand for security spending arises under fixed budget constraints, leaders must make tough choices. They can reallocate resources from domestic purposes towards military spending or leave the demand for security underfunded. Leaders can act strategically to place the burden of defense spending on those posing minimal threat to their tenure. However, if they face competition for office, they will likely have already allocated resources away from less salient constituents. Consequently, it is un- 6 likely that leaders can redirect resources without imposing costs on relevant constituents. Furthermore, relevant constituents still have clear incentives to place the burden on others even if defense spending contributes to a public good. This is evident in political debates over defense spending in the shadow of significant external threats and expectations of war (Narizny, 2003). Fiscal alternatives to borrowing (spending cuts, new taxes or monetary expansion) also risk macroeconomic stress (Ohanian, 1997) that can further risk a leader’s hold on power. As previous research demonstrates, poor economic performance has consequences for leaders of all regime types (Gasiorowski, 1995, Przeworski et al., 2000, Hibbs, 1977). As such, even if individuals do not discount the future, the macroeconomic consequences of non-borrowing strategies may risk a leader’s ability to remain in power. While borrowing can benefit all leaders, not all leaders can borrow. The price and quantity of borrowed funds is determined by its sovereign creditworthiness. As a government’s creditworthiness increases, borrowing costs fall and the amount it can borrow increases. Consequently, leaders can increasingly relax fixed budget constraints and allocate more resources towards security without altering the existing fiscal balance or risk macroeconomic liabilities. The costs and potential macroeconomic harm of the new security spending is thus pushed forward to an uncertain future. Individuals, not asked to pay additional resources in the present, are then less likely to support political rivals that challenge a leader’s power from either inside or outside the ruling coalition. Beyond avoiding the political unpopularity of taxes, spending cuts or inflation, affordable foreign capital can purchase political support by facilitating additional domestic fiscal transfers. If policies associated with military expenditure are themselves generating political opposition that restricts a leader’s preferred policies, political incumbents can use sovereign credit to ease opposition through fiscal means or purchase political support elsewhere. In sum, this permits leaders to provide ‘guns and butter’ to achieve their foreign policy goals and, in the process, increase military resources (Clark & Hart, 2003). This influence is similar to the effect of other sources of non-tax revenue that have a relationship with more hostile 7 and expensive foreign policies (McDonald, 2007). Lastly, military expenditure itself may serve domestic ends as it often has welfare externalities, such as employment, that benefit leftist governments (Whitten & Williams, 2011) or it also may serve as a source of patronage to military elites (Kono & Montinola, 2012). Those politicians with access to cheap credit will find it easier to increase military expenditure, without imposing costs on other segments of society, to further their political careers. As borrowing costs decrease and sovereign creditworthiness improves, it follows that leaders will be more willing to take advantage of credit and spend more on their military than similar states with higher borrowing costs or no access to credit markets. Note that the opportunity to borrow itself does not cause politicians to spend larger amounts on defense. However, it does make it more likely that, as their access improves, they will increase or maintain higher levels of military spending as demand for defense presents itself from both internal and external sources or existing government revenues fall. Conversely, as credit costs increase the political costs associated with military expenditure tighten and render expanding or maintaining military expenditure increasingly difficult. This reasoning leads to my first hypothesis. Hypothesis 1 An increase in a state’s sovereign creditworthiness is associated with an increase in military expenditure. The general argument claims that creditworthiness increases autonomy and relaxes constraints that would otherwise limit the influence of other demands on military expenditure. While it is difficult to measure the demand for military spending in a single variable, it is possible to capture the effects separately. Previous research indicates that a state’s external security environment is an important driver of military spending (Dunne & Smith, 2007, Nordhaus et al., 2012).3 As such, if the domestic constraints of poor credit terms are suf3 External variables do not entirely account for demand for military expenditure. As other have shown military spending may serve as a vehicle for welfare spending and thus a domestic source of demand (Whitten & Williams, 2011). I focus here on external threat because it is easily observed within the empirical framework. 8 ficiently salient, those states that face a mounting external threat will likely spend less on their military than creditworthy states faced with a similar threat. In the absence of credit, leaders may choose to do nothing or pursue a cheaper strategy of providing security. In each case, a state will end up spending less on its military than if it chose to respond to external threats by arming domestically. The second hypothesis outlines expectations following from this line of thought. Hypothesis 2 The effect of external threats on military expenditure will be smallest when creditworthiness is at its minimum and rise as creditworthiness increases. Data To test the hypotheses, I employ a time-series cross-sectional analysis of military expenditure for all states with available data. I draw on a variety of previous empirical models of military expenditure to inform my variable selection. Military expenditure Cross-national empirical analyses of military expenditure employ one of two dependent variables. Most often, researchers employ a state’s defense burden, the ratio of a state’s military expenditure to its gross domestic product (GDP) (Goldsmith, 2003, 2007, Fordham & Walker, 2005, Albalate et al., 2012, Phillips, forthcoming). Others instead estimate the log of a state’s military expenditure while controlling for a country’s economic size on the right hand side of the equation (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2004, Nordhaus et al., 2012). For several reasons, I follow Nordhaus et al. (2012) and adopt the latter approach, in which military expenditure is measured in constant dollars and adjusted for purchasing power parity.4 The defense burden approach is motivated by the idea that states have a fixed amount of 4 Nordhaus et al. (2012) merge the Correlates of War (COW) and SIPRI data. I only employ the recently updated military expenditure data from the Correlates of War project (Singer, 1987) to keep the data source consistent over all time periods. 9 resources from which they allocate military expenditure (Dunne & Smith, 2007). As I have discussed, states are not necessarily constrained by their domestic resources because they can borrow on sovereign credit markets. As such, the argument concerns the amount states spend on security that are influenced, but not constrained, by a state’s existing resources. This is conceptually different from the proportion of resources states allocate toward defense. Consequently, for the purposes of this study, the level of a state’s military spending more closely reflects the theoretical outcome of interest. While I believe this is the most appropriate specification for the question at hand, legitimate concerns remain over the measure’s cross-national and temporal comparability (Brzoska, 1995). As such, I demonstrate in the Supplementary Appendix that the central results are robust to employing the ratio of military expenditure to GDP as the dependent variable. Creditworthiness Researchers have generally relied on credit ratings produced by the private financial services firms Moody’s, Standard & Poor, or Fitch to measure sovereign creditworthiness (Archer et al., 2007, Beaulieu et al., 2012). These ratings are the result of risk assessments of a sovereign government’s likelihood of repayment and default. The rating schemes vary, but all consist of letter grades ranging no more than 20-values. Overall, these credit ratings presents several undesirable characteristics for cross-sectional time-series analysis. First, the data collection process is market driven and excludes states that lack sufficient creditor interest (Beaulieu et al., 2012). For example, a state can be creditworthy but lack the size to generate significant interest from a sizable number of international investors. Consequently, ratings on emerging market sovereigns generally begin in the mid-1990s when investor interest in sovereign bonds broke a threshold despite that many states borrowed substantial funds from private banks in decades past. Second, the sample excludes many non-creditworthy states. Governments that are aware of their poor credit risk are unlikely to hire a rating agency to assess their standing. As such, significant variation among states with poorer 10 credit prospects is unobserved. In light of ‘letter-grade ratings’ and other insufficient alternatives, I utilize credit ratings published by Institutional Investor magazine twice yearly since 1980. The dataset offers a broad sample of states and greater variance than alternatives and includes states from all levels of economic development and various regime types. It has been frequently employed in both economics and political science research to operationalize creditworthiness in crossnational time-series analysis (Ahlquist, 2006, Rose, 2005, DiGiuseppe et al., 2012). The Institutional Investor rating (IIR) spans from 0-100 (100 representing the most creditworthy) and reflects the opinion of ‘senior economists and sovereign-risk analysts at leading global banks and money management and securities firms’ anonymously polled by the magazine twice yearly and weighted in concordance with the assets of the expert’s firm (D’Ambrosio, 2005). Like the letter grades produce by ratings firms, the polled experts assess each state’s default risk. As such, the measure serves as a reliable indicator of the market’s perception of a state’s likelihood of repayment. I take the mean of the two yearly scores to create a yearly observation for each state. Where they overlap, this variable is highly correlated (0.96) with each of the more familiar ratings issued by credit ratings agencies. Additional covariates Existing empirical models indicate that military expenditure is a function of both external and internal variables (Goldsmith, 2003, 2007, Fordham & Walker, 2005, Albalate et al., 2012, Phillips, forthcoming). To capture a state’s external threat, I follow Fordham & Walker (2005) and include the logged sum of rival capabilities for each state. To construct the measure, I sum the COW composite index of national capabilities (CINC) of each state’s strategic rivals (Singer et al., 1972, Thompson, 2001). I also employ this variable to test the second hypothesis. Next, I include three binary variables indicating a state’s involvement in ongoing intrastate, interstate or extra-state wars as defined by the Correlates of War project (Sarkees & Wayman, 2010). Ongoing wars will likely drive demand for military spending as 11 states mobilize against both domestic and external threats to security.5 Beyond ongoing civil conflict, economic size and political institutions are the primary domestic determinants of military expenditure (Goldsmith, 2003, Albalate et al., 2012). As I mentioned, I include the log of GDP, adjusted for PPP, to control for the size of a state’s economy. Because research finds democracy to be a significant predictor of defense effort (Fordham & Walker, 2005, Goldsmith, 2003, 2007, Albalate et al., 2012), I also include the 21-point polity scale to control for the effect of regime type (Marshall et al., 2010). Furthermore, development and regime type are potentially confounding variables because they are predictors of sovereign creditworthiness. As such, controlling for their effects helps isolate the variance explained by each indicator and creditworthiness. Lastly, I discuss the robustness of the results to the inclusion of other variables beyond those employed in the primary analysis below.6 Estimation and results With all the relevant variables included, the dataset consists of a pooled cross-sectional timeseries that spans from 1981-2007 and includes 143 states. A data set of this type generates several complications for a standard linear model. First, it is possible that unobserved factors influence states to either raise or lower their military spending in unison. Cross-sectional time-series analysis of military spending is particularly susceptible to correlations among the panels because the decision of one state to increase military spending is likely to influence the strategic decisions of rivals or neighboring states (Sandler & Hartley, 1995, Flores, 2011). Following the recommendation of Beck and Katz (1995), I address this concern by estimating the models using Prais-Winsten regression with panel-corrected standard errors. 5 Some scholars include battle deaths as a way to capture the cost of ongoing war (Fordham & Walker, 2005, Nordhaus et al., 2012, Conrad et al., 2013). Because the timespan of this data is limited or does not indicate yearly deaths during war, I instead follow Goldsmith (2007) and employ dummy variables to capture the impact of war. 6 Summary statistics are available in the Supplementary Appendix. 12 Next, the analysis of a series, or multiple series, over time requires stationary data. In other words, the dependent variable must have a constant mean and constant variance over time. Here, an Augmented Dickey-Fuller test suggests that I can reject the null hypothesis of a unit root.7 This indicates that the data are likely stationary and standard regression techniques are suitable. Another complication arises from serial correlated errors. As others have noted, military expenditure is subject to budgetary inertia because spending is often driven by decisions made in prior periods and bureaucratic institutions can constrain spending reductions (Goldsmith, 2003, Nordhaus et al., 2012). I include a lagged dependent variable (LDV) to address this issue with the added benefit of permitting estimation of the dynamic long-term effects of the independent variables. Still, a Lagrange multiplier test indicates that even with the presence of the LDV first order autocorrelation remains. Consequently, I also include panel-specific first-order autoregressive correction.8 Next, research indicates that military expenditure has a strong influence on sovereign debt burdens (Brzoska, 1983, Looney & Frederiksen, 1986, Dunne & Smith, 2007, Smyth & Narayan, 2009). Sovereign debt burdens are highly predictive of creditworthiness as creditors are less willing to lend to states that already have large debt obligations. Consequently, I lag IIR, and other variables where necessary, one-year to minimize the possibility of endogeneity.9 Linear models To test the first hypothesis, I estimate the following linear equation: 7 I employed the ‘xtfisher’ command in Stata 12 to test for the presence of a unit root. This is the only test available for a dataset with unbalanced panels. Because this test is less than ideal, I also report error correction models in the Supplementary Appendix that are consistent with the results presented here. 8 I estimate the primary models in STATA 13 using the Beck and Katz’s (1995) ‘xtpcse’ command and correct for panel specific autocorrelation. 9 However, if endogeneity is present, it would introduce bias against my hypothesis because high debt burdens decrease creditworthiness. I also report GMM models below that also address problems of endogeneity should they be present. 13 ln(M ilExp.)i,t = φln(M ilExp.)i,t−1 + β1 lnGDPi,t−1 + β2 IIRi,t−1 + βXi,t + i (1) Where βXi,t is a matrix of control variables and their coefficients, φ is the coefficient for the lagged dependent variable and i is the error term. Model 1 of Table I presents the results of this estimation employing the full sample. Here, the IIR coefficient is positive and significant indicating that creditworthiness has a strong immediate influence on a state’s military expenditure. A 10-point increase, in IIR is associated with a 1.9% increase in military spending. This provides initial support for the first hypothesis, which states that creditworthy countries spend more on defense than those states will less favorable credit terms. [Table I Here] The next three models test the robustness of this finding. Model 2 excludes members of the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). Inclusion of these states may potentially drive the relationship observed in Model 1. OECD members receive highly favorable credit terms and posses levels of wealth conducive to military investment. Furthermore, non-OECD states’ access to credit markets is more sensitive to economic and political factors (Mosley, 2003), which potentially tempers the political advantages of credit. Similarly, Model 3 includes region-fixed effects to control for idiosyncratic regional attributes that may influence both military spending and creditworthiness unaccounted for by the covariates. Model 4 adds year-effects to explicitly control for any temporal dynamics or specific periods and events, such as the Cold War and War on Terror, that might influence global military spending. In each estimation, IIR remains positive and significant. In fact, the size of the coefficient almost doubles when excluding OECD states and remains stable with the inclusion of both region and yearly effects. Contrary to the focus of most previous research on the relationship between creditworthiness and war outcomes, Model 2 indicates 14 that the effect of creditworthiness is relevant to the foreign policy of those outside the industrial core and non-major powers. Models 3 and 4 provide confidence that the effect of creditworthiness is not isolated to regions, like Western Europe, that maybe predisposed to both high defense expenditure and favorable credit terms or specific to certain periods within the sample. Next, Model 5 presents the results of a system GMM estimator suggested by Arellano & Bond (1991) and Blundell & Bond (1998). The approach addresses several issues present in the first four models. First, several variables in the model maybe endogenous to military expenditure. Second, it is possible that the data used are stationary despite initial tests. Third, the models fail to account for unit heterogeneity. The GMM estimator uses a first difference transformation that addresses issues of both stationarity and unobserved effects without the need for fixed-effects.10 It also employs lags and differences of right hand side variables as instruments to address issues of endogeneity and collinearity.11 Overall, Model 5 demonstrates the results are robust to the issues address by the GMM estimator. Also, note that the p-value on the Hansen test indicates that the instruments are valid and not over-identified and that the p-value of the Arellano-Bond test indicates the absence second order correlation, which is necessary for the estimator to be consistent. The IIR coefficients in Table I demonstrate only the short-run effect on military expenditure. The long term effect (LTE) of creditworthiness is also relevant because new military expenditure is often budgeted several years in advance. I estimate the LTE employing the following equation: LT Ex = βˆ . 1−φˆ Where βˆ represents the coefficient of the independent variable of interest and φˆ is the coefficient of the lagged dependent variable. Corresponding with the significant short term effect, the bottom of Table I indicates that the LTE of IIR is positive and statistically significant at the 95% level in each of the five models.12 10 I also report country fixed-effects specifications in the Supplementary Appendix. I implement the estimator with the xtabond2 package in STATA 13. I was careful to limit the number of instruments to avoid inefficient estimates (Roodman, 2009). As such, I use two previous lags and differences of ln(GDP), IIR and the lagged dependent variable and treat other variables as strictly endogenous. 12 I assessed the statistical significance of each coefficient with simulations employing 10,000 draws of the coefficient and covariance matrices. 11 15 Figure 1 presents the 95% confidence intervals around the dynamic simulations of four scenarios based on Model 1’s estimates.13 One set of simulations holds IIR at either its maximum and minimum while holding all other variables at their mean or modal values.14 The other set holds a state’s Polity score at its minimum (-10) and maximum (10), again holding other covariates constant. The simulations begin with the log of military expenditure at the sample mean and allow it to adjust over time. [Figure 1] First, the IIR simulations demonstrate statistically significant differences between the two scenarios (they do not overlap) and also across each scenario. The significance of the LTE is apparent in both simulations by the third bar (at t+2) as the confidence intervals no longer overlap with the initial effect. Next, the differences between the two IIR scenarios increases over time. This demonstrates the importance of considering long term effect, which is dramatically larger than the initial effect of creditworthiness on military spending. Furthermore, this is consistent with expectations that bureaucratic inertia influences the timing of military spending changes. The simulations are also useful to compare the substantive short and long-run effects of different variables. Here, I contrast the substantive effects of creditworthiness and regime type given the latter’s recent attention in the literature (Fordham & Walker, 2005, Goldsmith, 2007, Albalate et al., 2012). The figure clearly illustrates that regime type’s significant short and long-run relationship with military spending. Figure 1 also demonstrates that the substantive effect of creditworthiness eventually exceeds that of regime type. This suggests that economic constraints influence military spending to a greater degree than institutional constraints.15 Further, creditworthiness’ larger effect on expenditure, relative to regime type’s often cited influence, provides a strong case for the appreciation of creditworthiness’ 13 I adopt a simulation technique advanced by Whitten and Williams (2011, 2012). The simulations employ 10,000 draws of the coefficient and covariance matrices. 14 I hold Polity and the war variables at their modal value and the remaining variables at their mean. 15 Similar simulations based on the Models 2-5 (see Supplementary Appendix) are consistent with this interpretation. 16 salient and substantial effect on security. Some caution is warranted in drawing this conclusion as previous literature suggests that democratic institutions increase creditworthiness (North & Weingast, 1989, Schultz & Weingast, 2003). However, the negative coefficient of regime type and the positive coefficient on IIR suggest that this relationship is not driving the results here. If regime type and creditworthiness were truly intervening variables in the manner suggested, their influence would move in the same direction.16 In other ways, this result is not surprising. While credit rating has a historical relationship with democracy, the relationship finds mixed evidence in analyses observing the past several decades (Archer et al., 2007, Saiegh, 2005). The conditioning effect of creditworthiness The second hypothesis maintains that creditworthiness conditions the effect of external threats on a state’s military expenditure. The models in Table II test this hypothesis by adding a multiplicative term of ln(Rival CINC) and a state’s IIR credit rating (βj (IIRi,t−1 ∗ ln(RivalCIN C)i,t−1 ) to each of the equations estimated in Table I. [Table II] Estimation of this model on the full sample (Model 6) indicates that the interaction term is statistically significant in the hypothesized direction. Because the coefficient provides limited information about the significance and substantive effects of the interaction, I graph the marginal effect of ln(Rival CINC) across the values of IIR rating in Figure 2. The solid lines represent the marginal effect, the dashed lines indicate 95% confidence intervals around the estimate and the histogram in the background indicates the distribution of IIR corresponding with the percentage of observations noted on the right Y-axis. Consistent with the hypothesis, the graph illustrates that the marginal effect of ln(Rival CINC) is 16 Additionally, I explored the potential for an interactive effect between creditworthiness and regime type based on Shea’s (2014) assertion that democracies are more sensitive to the economic costs of war. I find that creditworthiness’ effect is positive across regime type with no substantive difference in the effect. 17 statistically indistinguishable from zero at its lowest values. However, the marginal effect is both statistically and substantively significant as creditworthiness increases. In other words, ln(Rival CINC) has no effect when states have high borrowing costs but has a positive effect among states with more favorable credit terms. [Figure 2] A similar relationship to the one plotted in Figure 2 is evident when employing the estimates of Models 7-9. However, the GMM model, which eliminates unit heterogeneity, fails to demonstrate that IRR conditions impact on ln(Rival CINC). This result likely reflects that changes in rival capabilities are slow changing and invariant for states without rivals. As such, it is difficult to capture the effects in a model that effectively relies on within panel differences.17 In all, the results presented in Table II and the corresponding figure are consistent with the second hypothesis. High borrowing costs or the lack of credit market access makes it difficult to increase spending in response to the growing power of strategic rivals. This speaks to the constraining influence of poor credit terms even in the face of growing external threats and further demonstrates the influence of domestic political economy on a state’s provision of security. Further robustness checks For several reasons, I have excluded several potentially confounding variables from the above specifications that potentially threaten the validity of the findings. To alleviate concerns that the results are spurious, I identify several such variables and control for them in subsequent analysis that is available the Supplementary Appendix. First, many studies of military expenditure consider how a state’s alliances may reduce the burden of defense. Furthermore, states with strong ties to the international system may receive more favorable credit terms (Rose, 2005). To address this concern, I include the 17 A country-fixed effects specification (not reported here) presents similar results. 18 logged sum of the capabilities of a state’s defensive and offensive alliance partners, in a similar manner to the construction of ln(Rival CINC). It is also possible that a state’s governing capacity influences both the resources it can marshall for security and its ability to repay debts. With this in mind, I include a measure of state capacity collected by ArbetmanRabinowitz and Johnson (2008) that captures the ratio of a state’s actual tax revenues to its expected tax revenues. Next, alternative sources of non-tax revenues may reduce a country’s dependence on foreign capital and also correlate with a state’s credit terms as they may either increase a state’s ability to repay or harm institutional quality. Further, there are good reasons to believe that both sources of revenue are associated with higher military spending or hostile foreign policies as they augment budgets and potentially decrease the political influence of tax payers (Collier & Hoeffler, 2007, McDonald, 2007). As such, I include both the log of foreign aid inflows and the log of oil and gas revenue.18 Lastly, a state’s fiscal health may impact its ability to increase military spending independently of its creditworthiness. As such, I include a control for a government’s debt burden with the lagged ratio of public and publicly guaranteed external debt to GNI from the World Bank. In each of the models, the IIR variable remains positive and statistically significant. The additional models provide further evidence that a state’s credit terms have an important impact on a state’s military expenditure. Further, among the five potential variables included, I find that only debt burden has a statistically (negative) effect on a country’s military expenditure. Next, I demonstrate that the central results are robust to the use of two alternative indicators of credit risk. I present four models in Supplementary Appendix that employ either a binary indicator of credit access in which I code a state as having credit access if it has an S&P credit rating above ‘junk’ status (greater or equal to BBB) and those that have no credit rating or a ‘junk’ rating as zero for the period 1990-2007 or bond spreads (the difference between a country’s yearly average bond price and a benchmark price, the US 10-year Treasury bond). I find that having credit access and low bond spreads are 18 Aid data is sourced from the World Bank and I employ oil and gas revenue from Ross (2013). 19 both associated with higher military spending. I also use these measures to test the second hypothesis but only find the expected conditional relationship with the continuous bond spread variable. Lastly, my modeling choices depart from previous models of military spending in important ways. To demonstrate the results are not a product of my specification decisions, I test the how IIR performs in the preferred specifications of Nordhaus et al. (2012) and Fordham & Walker (2005). As reported in the Supplementary Appendix, IIR is positive and significant in both cases. Conclusion Researchers are beginning to appreciate the variety of ways in which governments fund security and the implications of different funding strategies for discrete outcomes like conflict and alliance formation. This article builds on this growing research by exploring how a government’s access to foreign capital influences the political economy of military spending. The empirical analysis is consistent with the argument that access to affordable foreign capital allows leaders to avoid the political consequences of more immediate methods of finance. These results build on previous work by demonstrating that sovereign creditworthiness has a broad influence on security beyond major powers and conflict outcomes and that this effect is apparent in both the short and long run. Further, the findings provide evidence that creditworthiness conditions the strategic behavior of states. Those states that must extract resources for spending primarily through domestic extraction are less likely to respond to growing external threats with increased military expenditure. As such, the political economy of international sovereign finance plays a role in limiting the provision of security within states even in the presence of external threats. The balance of state resources dedicated to domestic and external purposes lies at the 20 center on many world politics research questions. As such, the findings have clear relevance for a variety of foreign policy and world politics models that assume, either implicit or explicitly, that state and political leaders confront fixed-budget constraints. Consequently, appreciating the influence of sovereign creditworthiness on foreign policy has the potential to inform our understanding of a variety of outcomes scholars of world politics and policymakers care about. Replication data Replication files for this article can be found at www.prio.no/jpr/datasets. Acknowledgements The author would like to thank Michael A. Allen, Susan Allen, Jeff Carter, David H. Clark, Benjamin O. Fordham, Timothy Nordstrom, Michael J. Reese, Patrick Shea, and members of the Binghamton University World Politics Workshop. 21 References Ahlquist, John S (2006) Economic policy, institutions, and capital flows: Portfolio and direct investment flows in developing countries. International Studies Quarterly 50(3): 682–704. Albalate, Daniel; Germa Bel & Ferran Elias (2012) Institutional determinants of military spending. Journal of Comparative Economics 40: 279–290. Allen, Michael A & Matthew DiGiuseppe (2013) Tightening the belt: Sovereign debt and alliance formation. International Studies Quarterly 57(4): 647–659. Arbetman-Rabinowitz, Marina & Kristin Johnson (2008) Relative political capacity: Theory, model, data and updates. Paper presented at the International Sutdies Association Conference, San Francisco 26 March. Archer, Candace C; Glen Biglaiser & Karl D Jr. (2007) Sovereign bonds and the ”democratic advantage”: Does regime type affect credit rating agency ratings in the developing world? International Organization 61(2): 341–365. Arellano, Manuel & Stephen Bond (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies 58(2): 277–297. Banzhaf, H S & Wallace E Oates (2013) On fiscal illusion and ricardian equivalence in local public finance. National Tax Journal 66(3): 511–540. Barro, Robert J (1974) Are government bonds net wealth? Journal of Political Economy 82: 1095–1117. Barro, Robert J (1979) On the determination of the public debt. The Journal of Political Economy 87(5): 940–971. Beaulieu, Emily; Gary W Cox & Sebastian M Saiegh (2012) Sovereign debt and regime type: Re-considering the democratic advantage. International Organization 66(4): 709–738. Beck, Nathaniel. & Jonathan N Katz (1995) What to do (and not to do) with time-series cross-section data. American Political Science Review 89(3): 634–647. Blundell, Richard & Stephen Bond (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics 87(1): 115–143. Bordo, Michael D & Eugene N White (1991) A tale of two currencies: British and french finance during the napoleonic wars. The Journal of Economic History 51(2): 303–316. Brewer, John (1990) The Sinews of Power: War, Money, and the English State, 1688-1783. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Brzoska, Michael (1983) Research communication: The military related external debt of third world countries. Journal of Peace Research 20(3): 271–277. 22 Brzoska, Michael (1995) World military expenditures. In: Keith Hartley & Todd Sandler (eds.) Handbook of Defense Economics volume 1. Elsevier , 45–67. Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce; James D Morrow; Randolph M Siverson & Alastair Smith (2004) Testing novel implications from the selectorate theory of war. World Politics 56(03): 363– 388. Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce; Alastair Smith; Randolph M Siverson & James D Morrow (2003) The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge: MIT Press. Carter, Jeff & Glenn Palmer (forthcoming) Keeping the schools open while the troops are away: Regime type, interstate war and government spending. International Studies Quarterly. Citrin, Jack (1979) Do people want something for nothign: Public opinion on taxes and government spending. National Tax Journal 32(June): 112–30. Clark, David & Robert Hart (2003) Paying the piper? implications of social insurance payments for conflict propensity. International Interactions: Empirical and Theoretical Research in International Relations 29(1): 57–57. Collier, Paul & Anke Hoeffler (2007) Unintended consequences: Does aid promote arms races? Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 69(1): 1–27. Conrad, Justin; H.-C Kim & Mark Souva (2013) Narrow interests and military resource allocation in autocratic regimes. Journal of Peace Research 50(6): 737–750. D’Ambrosio, Mary (2005) A less risky world? Institutional Investor 30(9): 143–148. DiGiuseppe, Matthew (forthcoming) The fiscal autonomy of deciders: Creditworthiness and conflict initiation. Foreign Policy Analysis DOI: 10.1111/fpa.12044. DiGiuseppe, Matthew & Patrick Shea (forthcoming) Sovereign credit and the fate of leaders: Reassessing the democratic advantage. International Studies Quarterly DOI: 10.1111/isqu.12181. DiGiuseppe, Matthew R; Colin M Barry & Richard W Frank (2012) Good for the money? international finance, state capacity and civil conflict. Journal of Peace Research 49(3). Domke, William K; Richard C Eichenberg & Catherine M Kelleher (1983) The illusion of choice: Defense and welfare in advanced industrial democracies, 1948-1978. American Political Science Review 77(1): 19–35. Dooley, Peter C (1989) Ricardo and keynes on war finance. Atlantic Economic Journal 3(1): 21–33. Dunne, J P & Ron P Smith (2007) The econometrics of military arms races. In: Todd Sandler & Keith Hartley (eds.) Handbook of Defense Economics, Vol. II: Defense in a Globalized World. Amsterdam: Elsevier. 23 Easterly, William (2002) How did heavily indebted poor countries become heavily indebted? reviewing two decades of debt relief. World Development 30(10): 1677–1696. Ferguson, Niall (2001) The Cash Nexus: Money and Power in the Modern World, 1700-2000. New York: Basic Books. Flores, Alejandro Q (2011) Alliances as contiguity in spatial models of military expenditures. Conflict Management and Peace Science 28(4): 402–418. Flores, Gustavo A & Sarah E Kreps (2013) Political parties at war: A study of american war finance, 1789-2010. American Political Science Review 107(4): 833–848. Fordham, Benjamin & Thomas Walker (2005) Kantian liberalism, regime type, and military resource allocation: Do democracies spend less? International Studies Quarterly 4(1): 141–157. Garfinkel, Michelle (1994) Domestic politics and international conflict. The American Economic Review 84(5): 1294–1309. Gasiorowski, Mark J (1995) Economic crisis and political regime change: An event history analysis. American Political Science Review 89(4): 882–897. Goldsmith, Benjamin (2003) Bearing the defense burden, 1886-1989. Journal of Conflict Resolution 47(5): 551. Goldsmith, Benjamin (2007) Defense effort and institutional theories of democratic peace and victory: Why try harder? Security Studies 16(2): 189–222. Heo, Uk & John Bohte (2012) Who pays for defense? financing defense programs in the united states, 1947-2007. Journal of Conflict Resolution 56(3): 413–438. Hibbs, Douglas A (1977) Political parties and macroeconomic policy. The American Political Science Review 71(4): 1467–1487. Hume, David (1970 [1752]) Of Public Credit. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press. Kant, Immanuel (1795 [2003]) To Perpetual Peace: A Philosophical Sketch. Indianapolis, Indiana: Hacket. Kennedy, Paul M (1988) The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers. New York: Random House. Kono, Daniel & Gabriella R Montinola (2012) The uses and abuses of foreign aid: Development aid and military spending. Political Research Quarterly 66(3): 615–629. Lander, Mark (2010) Clinton speech offers policy overview. The New York Times: 9 September: A8. Looney, Robert E & Peter C Frederiksen (1986) Defense expenditures, external public debt and growth in developing countries. Journal of Peace Research 23(4): 329–338. 24 Marshall, Monty G; Kieth Jaggers & Ted Gurr (2010) Polity iv project: Data users manual. McDonald, Patrick J (2007) The purse strings of peace. American Journal of Political Science 51(3): 569–582. Mill, John S (1984 [1994]) Principles of Political Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Mintz, Alex (1989) ‘guns’ vs ‘butter’: A disaggregated analysis. American Political Science Review 83(4): 1285–1293. Mosley, Layna (2003) Global Capital and National Governments. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Narizny, Kevin (2003) The poltiical economy of alignment: Great britain’s comitments to europe, 1905-39. International Security 27(4): 184–219. Nordhaus, William; John R Oneal & Bruce Russett (2012) The effects of international security environment on national military expenditures: A multi-country study.”. International Organization 66(3). North, Douglass C & Barry R Weingast (1989) Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century england. The Journal of Economic History 49(4): 803–832. Oatley, Thomas (2010) Political institutions and foreign debt in the developing world1. International Studies Quarterly 54(1): 175–195. Ohanian, Lee E (1997) The macroeconomic effecst of war finance in the united states: World war ii and the korean war. American Economic Review 87(1). Phillips, Brian J (forthcoming) Civil war, spillover and neighbors’ military spending. Conflict Management and Peace Science DOI:10.1177/0738894214530853. Poast, Paul (2015) Central banks at war. International Organization 69(1): 63–95. Przeworski, Adam; Michael Alvarez; Joes A Cheibub & Fernando Limongi (2000) Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 1950-1990 volume 3. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Rasler, Karen A & William R Thompson (1983) Global wars, public debts, and the long cycle. World Politics 35(4): 489–516. Ricciuti, Roberto & Davide DiLaurea (2003) An experimental analysis of two departures from ricardian equivalence. Economics Bulletin 8(11): 1–11. Roodman, David (2009) How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system gmm in stata. The Stata Journal 9(1): 86–136. Rose, Andrew K (2005) One reason countries pay their debts: Renegotiation and international trade. Journal of Development Economics 77: 189–206. 25 Ross, Michael L (2013) Oil and gas data, 1932-2011. URL: http://hdl.handle.net/1902.1/20369 UNF:5:dc22RlDasveOTAJvwIjBTA== V2 [Version] Saiegh, Sebastian M (2005) Do countries have a democratic advantage? Comparative Political Studies 38(4): 366–87. Sandler, Todd & Keith Hartley (1995) The Economics of Defense. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Sanger, David E (2013) Fiscal deal fails to allay doubts on us global power. The New York Times: January 4: A6. Sarkees, Meredith R & Frank Wayman (2010) Resort to War: 1816-2007. Washington D.C.: CQ Press. Schultz, Kenneth A & Barry Weingast (1998) Limited governments, powerful states. In: Randolph M. Siverson (ed.) Strategic politicians, Institutions, and Foreign Policy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press , 15–50. Schultz, Kennth A & Barry Weingast (2003) The democratic advantage: The institutional sources of international competition. International Organization 57(1): 3–42. Seater, John J (1993) Ricardian equivalence. Journal of Economic Literature 31(March): 142–90. Shea, Patrick (2014) Financing victory: Demoracy, sovereign credit, and war. Journal of Conflict Resolution 58(5): 771–795. Singer, J D (1987) Reconstructing the correlates of war dataset on material capabilities of states, 1816-1985. International Interactions 14: 115–132. Singer, J D; Stuart Bremer & John Stuckey (1972) Capability distribution, uncertainty, and major power war, 1820-1965. Peace, War, and Numbers: 19–48. SIPRI (2010) SIPRI Yearbook 2010. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Slantchev, Branislav L (2012) Borrowed power: Debt finance and the resort to arms. American Political Science Review 106(4): 787 – 809. Smith, Adam (1776) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, eds. Campbell, RH and AS Skinner. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Smith, Ron P (1995) The demand for military expenditure. In: Keith Hartley & Todd Sandler (eds.) Handbook of Defense Economics volume 1. Elsevier. Smyth, Russell & Paresh K Narayan (2009) A panel data analysis of the military expenditureexternal debt nexus: evidence from six middle eastern countries. Journal of Peace Research 46(2): 235–50. 26 Thompson, William R (2001) Identifying rivals and rivalries in world politics. International Studies Quarterly 45(4): 557–586. Wagner, Richard E (1976) Revenue structure, fiscal illusion, and budgetary choice. Public Choice 25(1): 41–61. Whitten, Guy D & Laron K Williams (2011) Buttery guns and welfare hawks: The politics of defense spending in advanced industrial democracies. American Journal of Political Science 55(1): 117–34. Williams, Laron K & Guy D Whitten (2012) But wait, there’s more! maximizing substantive inferences from tscs models. Journal of Politics 74(3): 685–693. 27 Table I. Credit ratings & military expenditure LDV IIRt−1 log of Rival Cap.t−1 P olityt−1 log of GDPt−1 Intrastate War Extrastate War Interstate War Constant Observations R2 pHansen pAR(2)test # of Instruments LTE: IIRt−1 (1) All States 0.887*** (0.0215) 0.00188*** (0.000491) 0.00640*** (0.00209) -0.00437*** (0.00117) 0.100*** (0.0212) 0.144*** (0.0272) -0.0349 (0.0346) 0.0775† (0.0411) -0.890*** (0.238) 2864 0.993 (2) Non-OECD 0.881*** (0.0228) 0.00304*** (0.000705) 0.00573*** (0.00218) -0.00398*** (0.00129) 0.104*** (0.0230) 0.176*** (0.0332) -0.0841 (0.0630) 0.149** (0.0730) -0.941*** (0.276) 2201 0.991 (3) Region Effects 0.871*** (0.0240) 0.00172*** (0.000593) 0.00615*** (0.00226) -0.00205 (0.00149) 0.116*** (0.0230) 0.155*** (0.0268) -0.0333 (0.0377) 0.0764† (0.0410) -0.966*** (0.249) 2864 0.993 (4) Year Effects 0.887*** (0.0101) 0.00170*** (0.000338) 0.00597*** (0.00172) -0.00414*** (0.00108) 0.102*** (0.0108) 0.141*** (0.0226) -0.00901 (0.0348) 0.0619 (0.0402) -0.841*** (0.159) 2864 0.993 (5) GMM 0.852*** (0.0308) 0.00339*** (0.00117) 0.0113† (0.00580) -0.00315 (0.00217) 0.0836*** (0.0190) 0.180*** (0.0398) -0.0743 (0.0818) 0.142*** (0.0544) 2864 0.576 0.536 155 0.023*** (0.009) 0.017*** 0.026*** 0.014*** 0.015*** (0.004) (0.006) (0.005) (0.003) Standard errors in parentheses. † p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Models 1-4 estimated using panel corrected standard errors. Model 5 employs a systems GMM. 28 Table II. Credit ratings, rival capabilities & military expenditure LDV IIRt−1 log of Rival Cap.t−1 Rival Cap.t−1 ∗ IIRt−1 P olityt−1 log of GDPt−1 Intrastate War Extrastate War Interstate War Constant (6) All States 0.886*** (0.0215) 0.00355*** (0.000833) 0.000938 (0.00313) 0.000143*** (0.0000543) -0.00430*** (0.00117) 0.101*** (0.0211) 0.153*** (0.0269) -0.0422 (0.0346) 0.0779† (0.0402) -0.954*** (0.241) 2864 0.993 (7) Non-OECD 0.881*** (0.0227) 0.00406*** (0.00116) 0.00254 (0.00416) 0.0000963 (0.0000925) -0.00395*** (0.00129) 0.104*** (0.0230) 0.181*** (0.0326) -0.0933 (0.0647) 0.151** (0.0730) -0.974*** (0.279) 2201 0.991 (8) Region Effects 0.870*** (0.0240) 0.00288*** (0.000771) 0.00191 (0.00321) 0.000110** (0.0000542) -0.00214 (0.00150) 0.117*** (0.0229) 0.162*** (0.0266) -0.0385 (0.0374) 0.0742† (0.0406) -1.017*** (0.251) 2864 0.993 (9) Year Effects 0.886*** (0.0101) 0.00327*** (0.000796) 0.000804 (0.00327) 0.000134** (0.0000592) -0.00406*** (0.00108) 0.102*** (0.0108) 0.149*** (0.0226) -0.0170 (0.0351) 0.0630 (0.0402) -0.905*** (0.164) 2864 0.993 (10) GMM 0.858*** (0.0338) 0.00372** (0.00189) 0.00772 (0.00568) 0.0000977 (0.0000675) -0.00493** (0.00204) 0.114*** (0.0420) 0.154*** (0.0400) -0.0864 (0.0804) 0.116** (0.0527) Observations R2 pHansen pAR(2)test # of Instruments Standard errors in parentheses. † p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Models 1-4 estimated using panel corrected standard errors. Model 5 employs a systems 29 2864 0.179 0.527 108 GMM. 15 14.5 Polity Min. Polity Max. 14 ln(Military Expenditure) IIR Max. 13.5 IIR Min. 0 5 10 15 20 Years Figure 1. Predicting military expenditure over 20 years: Bars indicate the 95% confidence intervals around the estimated values. 30 4 .02 2 % of Obs. 3 .015 .01 Marginal Effect 1 .005 0 0 -.005 0 50 100 IIR Figure 2. The marginal effect of log of rival capabilities across IIR 31
© Copyright 2024