Output Decisions and Price-Matching: Theory and Experiment∗ Mongoljin Batsaikhan† Norovsambuu Tumennasan ‡ March 19, 2015 Abstract We study the effects of price-matching in a duopoly setting in which each firm selects both its price and output, simultaneously. We show that the availability of a pricematching option leads to the Cournot outcome in this setting. This result is a stark contrast to the one obtained in the standard price competition that the most likely market price in the presence of a price-matching option is the monopolistic price. We further confirm the validity of our theoretical result in an experimental study. Thus, both theoretical and experimental studies suggest that the effect of price-matching depends on whether the output is a choice variable for the firms. Keywords: Price matching, output decision, the Cournot outcome JEL Classifications: L00, L01, L02, D4 1 Introduction Retail businesses often use price-matching guarantees: if a product the seller carries is sold for a cheaper price by some other seller, then the seller will offer the product for the same low price. The retail giant Walmart, for example, offers price-matching guarantees frequently, especially during the Christmas shopping seasons. Since Salop (1986) price-matching has largely been considered an anti-competitive practice: a price-matching firm warns its competitors that it will not be underpriced; it thus eliminates the rivals’ incentive to underprice their product. For this reason, the market ∗ This version supersedes the previously circulated version “Price-Matching leads to the Cournot Outcome.” † School of Foreign Service in Qatar, Georgetown University. E-mail: mb1712@georgetown.edu ‡ Department of Economics and Business, Aarhus University, Denmark. Email: ntumennasan@econ.au.dk 1 price ranges from the monopolistic to the Bertrand price when the firms have options to price-match (Salop, 1986). Despite the multiplicity of equilibria, the literature considers the monopolistic price as the most likely outcome for two theoretical reasons: (i) the monopolistic price is the most profitable equilibrium price for the firms, and (ii) the monopolistic price alone survives the process of iterative elimination of weakly dominated strategies (Doyle, 1988). This result is further confirmed in a laboratory setting (Dugar, 2007). However, all the above-mentioned studies overlook the fact that the output decision is strategic.1 Particularly, these studies assume implicitly that the firms’ output adjusts automatically to the market demand. This assumption is perhaps realistic if the production takes place after firms receive pre-orders. In all other cases, because the production is costly, the firms must choose their output carefully. Therefore, in this paper we assume that the output decision is strategic for the firms. Specifically, we study a duopoly model in which each firm selects its output, price, and price-matching option, simultaneously. We first show that the Cournot outcome is the unique equilibrium outcome in our model. The key reason for our result is that at any equilibrium the total supply equals the market demand corresponding to the higher price in the market. As a result, it is possible for a firm to earn a positive profit even when it is underpriced – the reason why the Bertrand equilibrium is not an equilibrium in our setting. In addition, the availability of price-matching options allows the firms to protect their market share from possible underpricing. Subsequently, each firm responds to the other’s strategy in the same way as it would in the Cournot competition. Thus, the Cournot outcome emerges as the unique equilibrium in our model. The influential paper of Kreps and Scheinkman (1983) shows that the Cournot outcome is the only subgame perfect eqiulibrium (SPE) in the setting in which the firms first select their output and then set their prices.2 The timing of their setting therefore is different than ours: the firms make their output and pricing decisions simultaneously in our model. In fact, for the purpose of welfare comparison, the model in which the firms select their output and price at the same time in the Kreps-Scheinkman setting is a benchmark, but this model has not been explored to the best of our knowledge. We thus study the benchmark model and show that there is no pure equilibrium as long as 1 To the best of our knowledge almost the entire literature on price-matching does not model the firms’ output decisions explicitly. One exception is Tumennasan (2013), which we will discuss in greater detail later. 2 Davis (1999), Muren (2000), Anderhub et al. (2003) and Goodwin and Mestelman (2010) test the KrepsScheinkman predictions in a laboratory setting. The first three studies report that participants in general set their output higher than the Cournot output. Goodwin and Mestelman (2010) confirm this result for the case of inexperienced participants. However, experienced participants make similar choices in both the Kreps-Scheinkman and the standard Cournot setting. In the static setting with price-matching options, the subjects’ decisions in our main treatment are consistent with the theoretical prediction of our paper, the Cournot outcome. 2 the cost of production is positive.3 We then identify a mixed equilibrium in which the firms turn out to make an 0 profit in expectation. Therefore, the firms’ profit is unambiguously higher in the presence of a price-matching option. However, this result does not necessarily imply the negative impact of price matching on consumers because both firms’ price exceeds the Cournot price with a positive probability under this mixed equilibrium. In fact, for the linear demand case, we show that the effect of price matching on consumers is ambiguous. We next test our theoretical result in a laboratory setting. In our baseline treatment, we consider Salop’s standard model; subjects only selected their price and price-matching option. Our results for this treatment are highly consistent with the results of Dugar (2007)4 : the monopolistic outcome is the most likely equilibrium outcome in this setting. In our main treatment, subjects selected their price, price-matching option and output, simultaneously. The experimental results at the market level, i.e., the average market price and the subjects’ output, are highly consistent with the theoretical predictions of the paper. At the individual level, however, the results are not as consistent, but there is a clear trend indicating a convergence to the theoretical predictions. There is an extensive literature on price matching.5 Salop (1986) and Doyle (1988) argue that price-matching leads to the monopolistic price. Corts (1995) and Hviid and Shaffer (1999), on the other hand, counter that the Bertrand outcome is the more likely outcome. Specifically, Corts (1995) extends the price-matching policy to the price beating policy.6 Hviid and Shaffer (1999) introduce hassle costs, i.e., consumers have to bear certain costs to convince a price-matching firm that there is a lower price in the market. In their model, a firm can steal the other’s market share by underpricing because customers save the hassle costs by buying from the price cutter, thus, restoring the Bertrand price.7 We show that the Cournot price, a third price, emerges as the unique equilibrium outcome if the output is a choice variable for the firms. The closest study to ours is Tumennasan (2013). The main difference between Tumennasan (2013) and this paper is the timing of price and output decisions. He considers Kreps and Scheinkman (1983)’s two-stage setting in which the firms select their output in the first 3 Without price matching, the firms have an incentive to underprice the other slightly as long as the market price exceeds the marginal cost as in the Bertrand model. If both firms price their product at the marginal cost, each firm can earn a positive profit by increasing its price slightly and setting its production so that it sells its whole production at the new price. Thus, there is no pure equilibrium if the firms select their output and price at the same time. For more information see Proposition 2.8. 4 We discuss Dugar (2007) in more detail below. 5 See Arbatskaya et al. (2004) for more information. 6 If firms can beat the effective price of its competitors, then Salop (1986)’s results are restored (Kaplan, 2000). 7 Dugar and Sorensen (2006) take the model of Hviid and Shaffer (1999) to an experimental lab and find a significantly different price than the Bertrand price. 3 stage and make their pricing decisions in the second stage. In contrast, the firms make price and output decisions simultaneously in our setting. This difference in timing leads to a very different set of results: Tumennasan (2013) shows that a multiplicity of equilibria exists while we show that a unique equilibrium exists.8 Dugar (2007) studies the effects of price matching in a laboratory setting for the standard model in which firms do not select their output. He considers triopoly markets where firms select their price-matching options first, and then having observed its competitors’ pricematching options, each firm sets its price. He finds that the monopolistic outcome emerges in a laboratory setting. The results from our baseline treatment (i.e., the one without output choice) are consistent with Dugar (2007)’s results despite the differences between the two models. The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 lays out the model. Section 3 proves our main result that price-matching leads to the Cournot outcome. Section 4 reports our experimental results, and Section 5 concludes. We collect longer proofs in Appendix A and tables in Appendix B. 2 Theoretical Study 2.1 Model Two identical firms produce a homogeneous product; the market demand for this product is P (x) or D(p) = P −1 (p) where x and p stand for quantity and price, respectively. Each firm i selects (i) its output ki ∈ R+ , (ii) announced price pi ∈ R+ , and (iii) pricematching option oi ∈ {0, 1} where 1 means “match” and 0 means “do not match.” The buyers are aware of the firms’ choices. As a result, the price-matching options allow the firms to alter the actual price of its product. In particular, if a firm does price match, then it sells its product for the lowest price on the market. On the other hand, if the firm does not price match, then it sells its product for its announced price. The effective price of firm i is the price the firm sells its product for, i.e., pei (p1 , o1 , p2 , o2 ) := (1 − oi )pi + oi min{p1 , p2 }. The effective prices are instrumental for our analysis as they, along with the outputs, determine the sales quantity of the firms. To simplify the notation, we often write pei instead of pei (p1 , o1 , p2 , o2 ). We now formulate the sales quantity of the firms. Let pei and pej be the effective prices 8 Specifically, Tumennasan (2013) shows that price-matching weakly lowers the market price if the cost of production is “high”. If the cost of production is “low,” the effects of price-matching is ambiguous because the set of SPE prices includes the Cournot price in its interior. 4 for firms i and j (6= i), respectively. Then firm i sells e min {k oo n i , D(pi )} n xi (pe1 , pe2 , k1 , k2 ) = min ki , max D(p) − kj , D(p) 2 min {k , max{0, D(pe ) − k }} i i j if pei < pej if pei = pej = p (1) if pei > pej . The above formulation implicity assumes that the firms split the market if they announce the same price as long as each firm’s output is sufficiently large. In addition, the efficient rationing rule is used, i.e., the consumers with a higher valuation buy from the firm with the lower effective price. Let the strategy profile be ((k1 , p1 , o1 ), (k2 , p2 , o2 )). Then the profit of firm i = 1, 2 is πi (k1 , p1 , o1 , k2 , p2 , o2 ) = pei xi (pe1 , k1 , pe2 , k2 ) − cki where c > 0. The cost function is assumed to be linear in the formulation of the profit. We emphasize here that this assumption is not important in our analysis: the main result of the paper is valid as long as the cost function is strictly increasing and convex. We also maintain the following assumption throughout the paper. Assumption 2.1. P (x) is strictly positive on some bounded interval (0, x¯) on which it is twice continuously differentiable, strictly decreasing, and concave. For x ≥ x¯, P (x) = 0. We now turn our attention to the standard Cournot competition. Thanks to Assumption 2.1, one can easily show that the profit function P (x+y)x−cx is concave on [0, x¯ −y]. Let r(y) be the Cournot best response to the rival’s production y, i.e., r(y) = arg max0≤x≤¯x−y P (x + y)x − cx. The following lemma, which is instrumental in our analysis, is from Kreps and Scheinkman (1983). Lemma 2.2. (a) The Cournot best response rb is nonincreasing in y. In addition, rb is continuously differentiable and strictly decreasing over the range where it is strictly positive (b) r0 (y) ≥ 1, with strict inequality for y with r(y) > 0, so that y + r(y) is nondecreasing in y. Proof. See Kreps and Scheinkman (1983). Due to Assumption 2.1, there is a unique Cournot duopoly equilibrium with each firm supplying xc . Let pc := P (2xc ) and π c := (pc − c)xc . Furthermore, we find it useful to have 5 notations for the monopolistic price (pm ) and half of the monopolistic quantity (xm ). Let pm := arg maxp (p − c)D(p), xm := D(pm )/2 = arg maxx (P (2x) − c)x, and π m := (pm − c)xm . 2.2 Main Result In this subsection, we prove our main result: the only equilibrium outcome in our model is the one that results in the Cournot outcome. We will first study some properties of equilibria, which in turn will lead to our main conclusion. The first key property is that both firms set the same effective price at any equilibrium. If this is not the case, then the firm with the higher price must not be price-matching. Then it is optimal for the firm with the lower price to supply enough output to meet the market demand at its price because its price strictly exceeds c (see the formal proof). As a result, the firm with the higher price nets a non-positive profit because there is no demand beyond what the lower price firm supplies. However, the firm with the higher price can net half of the lower price firm by setting its price to that of the lower price firm and its output to half of the lower price firm’s output. Consequently, both firms set the same effective price at any equilibrium. In addition, the range of the equilibrium effective price must be in the set (c, P (0)). We collect these results below. Lemma 2.3. If (pe1 , pe2 ) is an equilibrium effective price pair, then pe1 = pe2 ∈ (c, P (0)). Proof. See Appendix A. We use the terminology market price at an equilibrium to refer to the common effective price the firms offer at this equilibrium. The following lemma asserts that, at an equilibrium, each firm supplies half of the market demand corresponding to the market price at this equilibrium. The key observation for this result is that at any equilibrium the total market supply equals the market demand corresponding to the market price at this equilibrium. Indeed if there is an excess supply (or excess demand), then one of the firms has an incentive to decrease (increase) its output without altering the market price. Now if the two firms do not supply the same output, then the one with the lower output has an incentive to increase its output while leaving the market price unaltered. Lemma 2.4. If the market price at an equilibrium is p ∈ (c, P (0)), then each firm’s output is D(p)/2 at this equilibrium. Proof. See Appendix A. 6 Lemmas 2.3 and 2.4 imply that each firm nets the same profit at a given equilibrium. In other words, for a given market price at an equilibrium, each firm nets half of the total market profit corresponding to this market price. In the lemma below, we first show that both firms price-match at each equilibrium. Indeed if a firm does not price-match, then the other firm, by slightly undercutting the equilibrium market price, can steal the market share of the non-price-matcher. The lemma also establishes a new and a tighter upper bound on the equilibrium market prices at the monopolistic price. If the market price strictly exceeds pm , then each firm has an incentive to set its price to the monopolistic price and its output to half of the monopolistic quantity. The deviating firm nets half of the monopolistic profit, which is superior to half of the total market profit corresponding to any price. Lastly, the lemma shows that, in the case that the market price at an equilibrium is strictly below the monopolistic price, both firms’ announced prices equal the market price. If the firms set different prices in this case, then the firm with the lower price has a profitable deviation. Specifically, this firm increases its price slightly and decreases its output to half of the market demand corresponding to its new price. At the deviation, the firm nets half of the total market profit corresponding to the altered price. But this profit increases as the price approaches the monopolistic price. Thus, both firms must have the same announced prices at a given equilibrium if the market price is strictly below the monopolistic price. Lemma 2.5. Consider any equilibrium strategy profile ((k1 , p1 , o1 ), (k2 , p2 , o2 )). (i) Both firms must price match, i.e., o1 = o2 = 1 (ii) The equilibrium market price p := pe1 = pe2 does not exceed pm , i.e., p ≤ pm . (iii) If the equilibrium market price p := pe1 = pe2 is strictly less than pm , i.e., p < pm , then p1 = p2 = p. Proof. See Appendix A. We are now ready to prove our main result that the only equilibrium in our setting is the one which results in the Cournot outcome. To see this, first recall that each firm’s output at an equilibrium is half of the market demand that corresponds to the market price at this equilibrium. Let this quantity be x∗ . Then each firm’s profit is (P (2x∗ ) − c)x∗ . If a firm sets its price to P (x∗ + r(x∗ )) and its output to r(x∗ ) and does not price-match, it sells r(x∗ ) for P (x∗ + r(x∗ )). The reason for this result is that the other firm cannot sell more than its output, x∗ . Clearly, (P (2x∗ ) − c)x∗ < (P (x∗ + r(x∗ )) − c)r(x∗ ) by the definition of r(·) as long as x∗ 6= xc . Thus, the market price must be the Cournot price. 7 Theorem 2.6. There exists only one equilibrium. Particularly, at the equilibrium it must be that (ki , pi , oi ) = (xc , pc , 1) for both i = 1, 2. Proof. See Appendix A. Remark 2.7. For our result the assumption that c > 0 is crucial. Indeed if c = 0, then all the prices from the Bertrand to the monopolistic price can be supported as an equilibrium price in our setting. To see this, suppose each firm sets its output to its D(0). Because the cost of production is 0, such a high output is not costly for the firms. Now each firm has enough output to satisfy the market demand at any price. Thus, we are back in the Salop world. 2.3 Benchmark Model In this subsection, we consider our model without price matching option. In other words, the firms choose their price and output simultaneously. Given that the option of price matching is not available for the firms, the announced price of a firm is the effective price of the firm. Thus, by substituting the announced prices for effective prices in expression (1) we determine the the sales quantity of the firms. We first point out that in the benchmark model, there is no pure equilibrium. In this setting, Lemmas 2.3 and 2.4 are still valid. But if the firms’ prices are the same and each firm’s output is half of the market demand corresponding to their prices, each firm has an incentive to underprice the other slightly while setting its output to the market demand corresponding to its new price. Thus, there is no pure equilibrium if the option to price match is not available to the firms. We state this result in the following proposition. Proposition 2.8. If a price matching option is not available to the firms, then there exists no pure equilibrium. We now focus our attention to identifying a mixed equilibrium in the benchmark model. Proposition 2.9. The symmetric, mixed strategy profile satisfying the two conditions below is an equilibrium.9 • An output and price combination, (ki , pi ), is in the support of firm i’s mixed strategy if (ki , pi ) = (D(pi ), pi ) and (ki , pi ) ∈ [c, P (0)] × [0, D(c)] 9 We are not sure whether this equilibrium is unique or not. Secondly, if we relax the assumption that the cost function linear, then the mixed strategy considered here is not necessarily an equilibrium. 8 • Each firm’s price is distributed according to the cumulative distribution function 0 F (p) = 1− 1 if p < c if p ∈ [c, P (0)) c p if p > P (0). Furthermore, at this equilibrium each firm’s profit is 0. Proof. See Appendix A. Proposition 2.9 and Theorem 2.6 lead to the conclusion that price matching affects the firms positively. When the firms do not have options to price match, at equilibrium each firm faces a risk of announcing a higher price than the other. In such cases, a firm sells none of its output and incurs a loss. On the other hand, such a risk is absent at the equilibrium when there is an option to price match. This elimination of the risk explains partly why price matching affects the firms positively. Therefore, the firms’ profit gain due to the availability of a price-matching option does not automatically lead to the loss in consumer welfare. In fact, the effect of price matching on consumers is ambiguous which we illustrate by the following example. Example 2.10. Suppose that the demand function is P (x) = a − bx where a > c. In , and pc = a+2c . The consumer surplus when the firms have an this case, P (0) = a, xc = a−c 3b 3 option to price match is the consumer surplus at the Cournot price which is found as follows: a Z a Z D(t)dt = CS(p) = pc pc a−t 2(a − c)2 dt = . b 9b Now we find the expected consumer surplus at the mixed equilibrium strategy profile identified in Proposition 2.9. Recall that at the equilibrium strategy, the firm with the lowest price produces the output which equals the market demand corresponding to the price of that firm. Thus, the firm with the lowest price sells all its output at its own announced price while the other sells nothing. Subsequently, if the minimal price on the market is p, then the consumer surplus, CS(p), is Z CS(p) = a Z D(t)dt = p p a a−t (a − p)2 dt = . b 2b Now let us calculate the cumulative distribution function, G(·), for the minimal market price at the mixed equilibrium. Because there are only two firms, the minimum market price is the second order statistic which is known to be distributed according to the following 9 distribution: 2 2 c c c − 1− = 1− , for all p ∈ [c, P (0)] ≡ [c, a]. G(p) = 2F (p) − (F (p)) = 2 1 − p p p 2 Observe here that the distribution for the minimal market price is discontinuous only at P (0) = a. However, this does not cause any issue in our calculation of the expected consumer surplus because the consumer surplus at a is 0. The expected consumer surplus in the absence of a price-matching option is: Z E[CS] = a Z a CS(p)dG(p) = c p (a − p)2 c2 c2 dp = bp3 b 3 a2 − 4ac a + + ln 2 2 2c c . Observe here that the consumer surplus in the presence of price matching exceeds the 2 2 one in the absence of price matching when a = 2c (E[CS] = cb (ln(2) − 0.5) < 2c9b = CS(pc )). However, this inequality is reversed once a = 4c. 3 3.1 Experimental Study Experimental Setup We conducted a laboratory experiment to test the results predicted by theory. The experiment involved two treatments: T1, where subjects chose a price and decided whether to price-match, and T2, where subjects chose a price, an amount of output to commit to produce, and decided whether to price-match or not. We recruited 36 subjects (18 for each treatment) from the School of Economics and Business at the Mongolian National University and conducted the experiment in Ulaanbaatar, Mongolia on May 23rd, 2014. Subjects were randomly matched and played for 10 rounds with the same opponent. Decisions were logged via computer and the identities of opponents were kept anonymous. After the subjects granted their consent, subjects were provided with oral and written instructions in Mongolian. The instructions carefully explained the structure of the experiment and specified the demand function. Subjects were given an opportunity to ask questions about the experiment. The experiment was conducted via computer, with two practice rounds to ensure that the subjects were familiar with the computer program. In each round of T1, subjects chose their price and decided whether to price match or not; in T2 they also chose their output. In addition, each subject was provided an on-screen calculator which one could use to calculate the profits by entering her and her opponent’s hypothetical decisions. There is a long tradition of providing a profit table or a profit calculator in 10 experiments involving the Cournot duopolies (Fouraker and Siegel, 1963; Holt, 1985; Huck et al., 1999).10 In both treatments, the marginal cost of production is $40 for each firm, and the market demand function is D(p) = 160 − p. In each round, the market cleared after both subjects in the same group made decisions. Each subject’s profit was calculated and the decisions and profits of both subjects were revealed to both subjects. These results were accumulated into a result table for each round. Subjects were paid 3000 Mongolian Tugrik (MNT) as a show-up fee and 1 MNT for each unit of profit they earned throughout the actual 10 rounds of the experiment. 3.2 Results Treatment 1. For this treatment, Salop (1986) shows that the equilibrium price can range between the Bertrand price, 40, and the monopolistic price, 100. The firms must price match in all equilibria except the one in which both firms set their prices to the Bertrand price. There are strong theoretical arguments that the monopolistic price is the most likely equilibrium outcome: (i) the monopolistic price is the only equilibrium price that survives the process of iterative elimination of weakly dominated strategies (Doyle, 1988), and (ii) out of the all equilibria prices the monopolistic one results in the highest profit to the firms.11 Our experimental results strongly support that the monopolistic price is the most likely outcome. First of all, the subjects use the price matching option overwhelmingly: there were only 4 cases in all 10 rounds (that is, out of 180 decisions) where a subject chose not to price match. In addition, each non-price-matching subject in these cases selected a lower price than its opponent. Secondly, the subjects set their prices to the monopolistic price in 73.3% of all decisions (132 times out of all 180 cases). We report these results in Table 1. The results are even stronger if we concentrate on the last five periods: the subjects set their prices to the monopolistic price in 83.3% of all decisions. There were six instances in which a subject set a price greater than 100, but in all these instances the opponent always set her price to 100. In fact, all but one game in the last 5 rounds resulted in the prices of 100 or 99. 10 Requate and Waichman (2011) find that the experimental results in Cournot duopolies do not depend on whether a profit table or a profit calculator has been provided to the participants. 11 It is straightforward to see that at each equilibrium the two firms earn equal profit. In addition, because the monopolistic price brings the highest total profit to the firms, this price is Pareto optimal from the firms’ perspective. 11 Dugar (2007) conducts an experimental study that investigates the effects of price matching in the standard model in which the firms do not make output decisions. Even though our Treatment 1 differs from Dugar (2007)’s in some aspects, our results are consistent with Dugar (2007)’s12 : the monopolistic price is the most likely equilibrium price in the standard model of price matching where output decisions are not considered. Treatment 2. In Section 2.2 we showed that the only equilibrium for this treatment is the Cournot outcome. Specifically, theory predicts that the subjects price-match and set their price and output to the Cournot price and output, respectively. The experimental results of this treatment did not converge to the theoretical predictions as easily as the results of T1 did. However, the trend shows a clear convergence to the theoretical predictions. We first analyze the results at the market level. In our experimental setup, the Cournot price is $80, and the Cournot production of each firm is 40. Although the Cournot outcome did not prevail in any market in the first period, it did prevail in 5 out of 9 markets (55.56%) in the last two periods (see Table 2). In these markets, the minimal price selected by the participants is the Cournot price, and the two opponents set their output to the Cournot output. We next analyze the results at the individual level by three variables – the price matching option, price and output. The subjects price matched in 177 out of 180 total decisions. The prices selected by the subjects are more dispersed, but the mode is at 80 – the Cournot price. This price is selected 55 times which is 20 more than the second highest selected price, 100. These results are shown in Table 3. In Figure 1 we show the frequency of the chosen prices, period by period. The number of subjects who set their price to the Cournot price reaches the highest (9 subjects or 50%) in the last two rounds. It is also worth noting that the results from this treatment are significantly different from the ones in Treatment 1: the average price of subjects’ price choice is significantly lower than the monopoly price of 100 – the predicted price in the baseline treatment. The Mann-Whitney test for the difference in prices between the two treatments is significant at 1% level, and the result stays the same in linear regression models with period trend and subject fixed effects. In terms of the output choice of the subjects, they set the output to the Cournot output 104 times (57%) and to the monopolistic quantity 21 times (12%). These results are shown in Table 4. 12 In Dugar (2007)’s study, subjects are divided into groups of three, and each subject chooses her pricematching option first and then sets her price after observing the price-matching decisions of her group members. 12 Now we consider all the price, output and price-matching decisions jointly. Panel A of Table 5 shows the frequencies and percentages of subjects who chose the exact Cournot price and quantity with price matching over 10 periods. Panel B exhibits the frequencies and percentages of subjects who chose a price higher than Cournot but the Cournot quantity with price matching. This table suggests that the subjects are converging to the Cournot outcome. The Cournot competition has received a significant amount of attention from experimental economists. Holt (1985) finds that with fixed pairs of participants the results of the Cournot experiments lie somewhere between the Cournot and the collusive outcomes.13 Our results are consistent with Holt’s results. Given that the experimental setups for the standard Cournot competition is much simpler than ours, it perhaps is unreasonable to expect that our experimental results converge perfectly to the theoretical prediction. 4 Conclusion In this paper we study the effects of price-matching in a duopoly setting in which each firm selects both its price and output, simultaneously. Our theoretical result shows that the unique equilibrium outcome in this setting is the Cournot outcome. In addition, our experimental results support our theoretical result. References Vital Anderhub, Werner G¨ uth, Ulrich Kamecke, and Hans-Theo Normann. Capacity Choices and Price Competition in Experimental Markets. Experimental Economics, 6(1):27–52, June 2003. Maria Arbatskaya, Morten Hviid, and Greg Shaffer. On the incidence and variety of low-price guarantees. Journal of Law & Economics, 47(1):307–32, 2004. Kenneth S. Corts. On the robustness of the argument that price-matching is anti-competitive. Economics Letters, 47(3-4):417–421, 1995. Douglas D. Davis. Advance production and Cournot outcomes: an experimental investigation. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 40(1):59–79, September 1999. Christopher Doyle. Different selling strategies in bertrand oligopoly. Economics Letters, 28 (4):387–390, 1988. 13 Huck et al. (2001) replicates Holt’s results. 13 Subhasish Dugar. Price-Matching Guarantees and Equilibrium Selection in a Homogenous Product Market: An Experimental Study. Review of Industrial Organization, 30(2):107– 119, March 2007. Subhasish Dugar and Todd Sorensen. Hassle costs, price-matching guarantees and price competition: An experiment. Review of Industrial Organization, 28(4):359–378, June 2006. L. Fouraker and S. Siegel. Bargaining behavior. McGraw-Hill, London, 1963. David Goodwin and Stuart Mestelman. A note comparing the capacity setting performance of the Kreps-Scheinkman duopoly model with the Cournot duopoly model in a laboratory setting. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 28(5):522–525, September 2010. Charles A Holt. An Experimental Test of the Consistent-Conjectures Hypothesis. American Economic Review, 75(3):314–25, June 1985. Steffen Huck, Hans-Theo Normann, and Jorg Oechssler. Learning in Cournot Oligopoly–An Experiment. Economic Journal, 109(454):C80–95, March 1999. Steffen Huck, Wieland Muller, and Hans-Theo Normann. Stackelberg Beats Cournot: On Collusion and Efficiency in Experimental Markets. Economic Journal, 111(474):749–65, October 2001. Morten Hviid and Greg Shaffer. Hassle costs: The achilles’ heel of price-matching guarantees. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 8(4):489–521, 1999. Todd R. Kaplan. Effective price-matching: a comment. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18(8):1291–1294, 2000. David M. Kreps and Jose A. Scheinkman. Quantity precommitment and bertrand competition yield cournot outcomes. Bell Journal of Economics, 14(2):326–337, 1983. Astri Muren. Quantity precommitment in an experimental oligopoly market. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 41(2):147–157, February 2000. Till Requate and Israel Waichman. A profit table or a profit calculator? A note on the design of Cournot oligopoly experiments. Experimental Economics, 14(1):36–46, March 2011. Steven C. Salop. Practices that (credibly) facilitate oligoply coordination. In Joseph E. Stiglitzs and Frank G. Mathewson, editors, New Developments in the Analysis of Market Structure, pages 265–290. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1986. 14 Norovsambuu Tumennasan. Quantity precommitment and price matching. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 49(5):375–88, 2013. Appendix A: Proofs Proof of Lemma 2.3. Let ((k1 , p1 , o1 ), (k2 , p2 , o2 )) be an equilibrium strategy pair. First we show that ki > 0 for i = 1, 2. On the contrary, suppose ki = 0 for some i ∈ {1, 2}. Clearly, i nets 0 profit. In this case, j is essentially a monopolist. It thus must be that kj = 2xm , pj = pm and πj (k1 , p1 , o1 , k2 , p2 , o2 ) = 2π m . If i sets its output to xm and price to pm , then i nets π m , which is positive. Thus, ki > 0 for i = 1, 2. If pei < c for some i, then the firm with the lowest announced price must net a strictly negative profit because both firms produce a strictly positive output. Thus, pei ≥ c for i = 1, 2. We now dispose of the pei = pi = c case. Suppose that pei = pi = c. In this case, firm i nets a non-positive profit. In addition, i must not net a negative profit because i nets 0 profit by producing 0 output. Thus, i nets 0 profit. Observe now that firm i has a profitable deviation unless pj = c, where j 6= i. Specifically, if pj > c, then by setting its price to c + , where > 0 satisfies that c + < pj , and its output to D(c + )/2, firm i nets D(c + )/2, a positive profit. Thus, pj = pi = c which implies that both firms make 0 profit (recall that the firms can always net 0 profit by setting their output to 0). Furthermore, it must be that ki + kj ≤ D(c). Otherwise, one of the firms cannot sell its full capacity, which implies that the firm earns a negative profit, a contradiction. Without loss of generality, assume that the firm with the higher output is firm i. Then by setting its price to c + δ, where δ > 0 satisfies D(c + δ) − kj > 0, and its output to D(c + δ) − kj , i nets δ (D(c + δ) − kj ), a positive profit. This is a contradiction. Thus, each firm i must set its effective price strictly higher than c, i.e., pei > c. Now let us show that pe1 = pe2 . On the contrary, suppose that c < pei < pej . This means that pi < pj and oj = 0. As a result, firm i nets pi min{ki , D(pi )} − cki . First observe that pi < P (0). Otherwise, firm i’s profit is not positive. But if i sets its price to pm (which is strictly lower than P (0), by definition) and its output to xm , then it earns a positive profit, which is a contradiction. Thus, pi < P (0) or equivalently, D(pi ) > 0. Firm i’s profit is pi min{ki , D(pi )} − cki . Because pi ∈ (c, P (0)) and D(pi ) > 0, observe that firm i’s profit for a given price pi is maximized at output D(pi ). In other words, it must be that ki = D(pi ). Subsequently, firm j’s profit is non-positive because D(pj ) − ki < 0, for all pj > pi and ki = D(pi ). However, if firm j sets its price to pi and its output to D(pi )/2, then it nets (pi − c)D(pi )/2, a positive profit. This is a contradiction. 15 Finally, let us show that pe1 = pe2 < P (0). On the contrary, suppose that pei = pej ≥ P (0). Then neither firm’s profit is positive. But if a firm sets its price to pm (which is strictly lower than P (0) by definition) and its output to xm , then the firm nets a positive profit. This is a contradiction. Proof of Lemma 2.4. We first show that k1 + k2 = D(p). Recall that p ∈ (c, P (0)), due to Lemma 2.3. If k1 + k2 < D(p), then each firm i nets (p − c)ki . But firm i can net (p−c)(D(p)−kj ) by changing only its output to D(p)−kj . This is a profitable deviation since D(p) − kj > ki . If k1 + k2 > D(p), then there is some excess output in the market. Let j be the firm with the higher capacity. Then j earns p (min{kj , max{D(p)/2, D(p) − ki }}) − ckj . Since kj ≥ ki and k1 + k2 > D(p) (by assumption), kj > max{D(p)/2, D(p) − ki }. This means that firm j does not sell its entire output at p. If j decreases its output slightly but keeps its effective price at p, then j’s income does not change but its cost of production decreases. Hence, firm j has a profitable deviation which would be a contradiction. Thus, it must be that k1 + k2 = D(p). Finally, let us show that k1 = k2 = D(p)/2. Suppose ki < D(p)/2. Then it must be that kj > D(p)/2 > D(p) − kj = ki . Consequently, firm i nets (p − c)ki . If firm i increases its output slightly to ki + ( > 0 is small enough so that D(p)/2 > ki + ) and sets its effective price to p, then it earns (p − c)(ki + ) > (p − c)ki . This is a contradiction. Proof of Lemma 2.5. Due to Lemma 2.3, it must be that pe1 = pe2 = min{p1 , p2 } := p > c. In addition, it must be that k1 = k2 = D(p)/2 (Lemma 2.4). Thus, both firms net (p−c)D(p)/2. To the contrary of (i), suppose oi = 0. This and the result that pe1 = pe2 = p > c (Lemma 2.3) imply that pi = p. Now firm j, by setting its price to p − , where > 0, and its output to D(p − ), nets (p − − c)D(p − ), which is a profitable deviation if is sufficiently small. Therefore, oi = 1. To the contrary of (ii), suppose p > pm . If firm i sets its price to pm and its output to xm , then it nets (pm − c)xm = (pm − c)D(pm )/2. But by the definition of pm , (p − c)D(p)/2 < (pm − c)D(pm )/2. Hence, i has a profitable deviation which is a contradiction. To prove (iii), suppose that p < pm and pi = p < pj . From the first part of this lemma we already know that oj = 1. Thanks to Lemma 2.4, firm i nets (p − c)D(p)/2. If firm i sets its price to p¯ = min{pj , pm } and its production to D(¯ p)/2, then it nets (¯ p − c)D(¯ p)/2. As m the function (y − c)D(y)/2 is concave and maximized at p , it must be that (¯ p − c)D(¯ p)/2 > (p − c)D(p)/2. Therefore, i has a profitable deviation which is a contradiction. Thus, p1 = p2 = p if p < pm . Proof of Theorem 2.6. First let us show that the strategy profile in which both firms price match and set their output to xc and their price to pc is an equilibrium. At this equilibrium, 16 each firm nets (pc − c)xc . Suppose firm i deviates unilaterally by setting its effective price to p ∈ [c, pc ] and its production to k. Then it earns p min {k, D(p) − xc } − ck because D(p)−xc > D(p)/2, for all p < pc . For any given p, observe that the above expression is maximized at k = D(p) − xc . Thus, firm i earns at most (p − c)(D(p) − xc ) by setting its price to p. Now let us find the maxp≤pc (p − c)(D(p) − xc ). Denote x = D(p) − xc . Then our problem is equivalent to maxx≥xc (P (x + xc ) − c)x. This expression, by the definition of r(·), is maximized at x = r(xc ) = xc . Thus, maxp≤pc (p − c)(D(p) − xc ) = (pc − c)xc . Therefore, there is no profitable deviation for firm i in which its price does not exceed pc . Suppose firm i deviates unilaterally by setting its effective price to p > pc and its production to k. Then it earns p min {k, max{D(p) − xc , 0}} − ck. Similarly to the previous case one can see that firm i does not have any incentive to increase its price above pc . This completes the proof that the proposed strategy profile is an equilibrium. We now show that there is no equilibrium in which the resulting effective price is different from pc . On the contrary, suppose there is an equilibrium at which the effective price is p∗ 6= pc . Due to Lemma 2.3, p∗ ∈ (c, P (0)). When this result is combined with Lemma 2.4, we obtain that firm i nets (p∗ − c)D(p∗ )/2 or (P (2x∗ ) − c)x∗ where x∗ = D(p∗ )/2. Now if firm i sets its price to p = P (x∗ + r(x∗ )) and its output to D(p) − x∗ , then it earns (p − c) max{0, (D(p) − x∗ )} = (P (x∗ + r(x∗ )) − c)r(x∗ ). The last equality is due to the fact that x∗ < D(0) and that r(x) > 0 for all x ≤ D(0). Now observe that, by the definition of r(·), we obtain that (P (x∗ + r(x∗ )) − c)r(x∗ ) > (P (2x∗ ) − c)x∗ . Hence, no p∗ 6= pc is an equilibrium effective price. The fact that p∗ = pc is the unique equilibrium effective price along with Lemmas 2.4 and 2.5(iii) yields the uniqueness of the equilibria. Proof of Proposition 2.9. Fix a firm i ∈ {1, 2}, and suppose i plays the mixed strategy described in the proposition. We now show that all the strategies in the support of firm j’s strategy described in the proposition maximizes firm j’s profit. Any price outside of the support of j’s mixed strategy, i.e., any price pj such that pj < c or pj > P (0), does not bring a nonnegative profit to j. If pj = P (0), then the maximal profit of firm j is 0 which j can achieve by setting its output to 0. Consider now any pj = p ∈ [c, P (0)). By combining p with an output kj , firm j nets 17 p min{kj , D(p)}(1 − F (p)) − ckj . Observe here that any kj that strictly exceeds D(p) does not maximize the expression above. Indeed if kj > D(p), j would improve its profit by setting its output to D(p). On the other hand, if kj ∈ [0, D(p)], then j’s profit is pkj (1 − F (p)) − ckj = (p(1 − F (p)) − c) kj . Now by substituting that F (p) = 1 − pc in the expression above, we obtain that the expression above equals 0 for any kj ∈ [0, D(p)]. Given that for all p ∈ [c, P (0)), max pkj (1 − F (p)) − ckj = 0 and D(p) = arg maxkj pkj (1 − F (p)) − ckj , we obtain that all the output and price combinations in the support of the mixed strategy given in the proposition maximizes firm j’s profit against firm i’s strategy. In addition, because this maximal profit is always 0, we have proved that the mixed strategy profile in the proposition is an equilibrium. 18 Appendix B: Tables and Figure Table 1: Frequency of Price and Price Matching Decisions in Treatment 1 (all rounds) Price 79 80 89 90 95 97 98 99 100 101 110 119 120 140 Total All Rounds Price Matching No Yes Total 1 2 3 0 3 3 1 1 2 1 2 3 0 3 3 0 1 1 0 1 1 1 15 16 0 132 132 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 12 12 0 1 1 4 176 180 Rounds 6-10 Price Matching No Yes Total 1 0 1 1 0 7 75 8 75 0 0 1 5 1 5 2 88 90 Notes: The table shows the subjects’ choices for price and price matching in Treatment 1. The first half of the table shows the frequencies of prices chosen along with its price matching choices in all ten periods. The second half of the table shows the frequencies of prices chosen along with its price matching choices in the last five periods. The prices ranged from 79 to 140. The most frequent choice was at 100, which is the monopoly price. 19 Table 2: The Percentage of Games that Result in the Cournot Outcome Period Freq. 1 0 2 3 3 4 4 2 5 1 6 4 7 3 8 3 9 5 10 5 Total 30 Percent 0.00 33.33 44.44 22.22 11.11 44.44 33.33 33.33 55.56 55.56 33.33 Notes: The table shows the frequency and its percentage of Cournot outcome out of all possible market equilibria over ten periods. Each pair of subjects is considered as a market, and there were 9 markets with 18 subjects in each round. 20 Table 3: Frequency of Price and Price Matching Decisions in Treatment 2 Price 70 75 76 78 79 80 82 84 85 89 90 92 95 98 100 101 110 150 Total All Rounds Price Matching No Yes Total 0 2 2 0 8 8 0 3 3 1 2 3 0 5 5 2 53 55 0 1 1 0 4 4 0 13 13 0 4 4 0 30 30 0 3 3 0 9 9 0 2 2 0 35 35 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 1 1 3 177 180 Rounds 6-10 Price Matching No Yes Total 0 1 1 0 2 2 0 3 3 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 32 32 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 6 2 13 1 6 2 6 2 13 1 6 0 0 18 1 18 1 0 90 90 Notes: The table shows the subjects’ choices of price and price matching in Treatment 2. The first half of the table shows the frequencies of prices chosen along with its price matching choices in all ten periods. The second half of the table shows the frequencies of prices chosen along with its price matching choices in the last five periods. The prices ranged from 70 to 150. The most frequent choice was at 80, which is the Cournot price. Table 4: Frequency of Output Decisions in Treatment 2 Output Frequency 30 21 35 15 38 40 6 104 41 1 42 2 44 45 4 13 48 50 1 12 60 1 Notes: The table shows the frequency of outputs chosen by subjects in all ten periods. The output choices ranged from 30 to 60. The most frequent one was at 40, which is the Cournot output. 21 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0 10 5 0 Frequency 5 10 1 60 70 80 90 100 60 70 80 90 100 60 70 80 90 100 60 70 80 90 100 60 70 P Graphs by Period Figure 1: Frequency of Price Choices of the Subject over 10 Rounds 22 80 90 100 Table 5: The Percentage of Subjects who set Their Output to the Cournot Output Panel Period Frequency 1 3 2 3 3 4 4 4 5 4 6 7 7 4 8 5 9 6 10 8 Total 48 A Panel B Percent Frequency Percent 16.67 5 27.78 16.67 9 50.00 22.22 14 77.78 22.22 10 55.56 22.22 8 44.44 38.89 13 72.22 22.22 10 55.56 27.78 10 55.56 33.33 12 66.67 44.44 12 66.67 26.67 103 57.22 Notes: The table shows the subjects’ choices for price and outcome in Treatment 2. Panel A of Table 5 shows the frequencies and percentages of subjects who chose the exact Cournot price and quantity with price matching over 10 periods. Panel B exhibits the frequencies and percentages of subjects who set their price (weakly) higher than the Cournot price and selected the Cournot quantity along with the price matching option. 23
© Copyright 2024