Why Germany should leave the Euro Alfred Steinherr, Free University of Bolzano 1. Introduction Is the current Euro crisis an unfortunate accident or the unavoidable consequence of an ill-fated design? Can the Euro overcome the current crises, and can its management/governance mature to acknowledge its limitations and costs to evolve into a monetary system with lesser ambitions and lesser risks? This is the question posed in this paper. In Section 2 I argue that the current Euro crisis was due not to an unforeseeable accident but to a sloppy and irresponsible foundation of the EMU as embodied in the Treaty of Maastricht. Even worse, as this Treaty the culmination of decades of preparatory thinking, negotiations and trials is the best compromise the European Union could deliver we should not be carried away by optimistic assessments of what future reforms will be able to achieve. Section 3 makes the point that the various fundamental values of the European Union are in conflict with each other and make a harmonious monetary union impossible. Therefore, some of the fundamentals must be given up or, alternatively, the composition of the Euro area. Section 4 turns to the miserable management of the crisis so far and reassesses German responsibility. Section 5 concludes. 2. The Maastricht Treaty as the main cause of the Euro crises A national currency gains its credibility over time through the policies of government and the central bank. The differences in the international acceptance of, for example, the D-Mark and the Italian lira, had little to do with the general economic performance of the German and Italian economies – which were fairly similar in terms of economic growth -, but more with the quality of institutions: the credibility of and trust in the government and its agencies, the congruence between declarations of objectives and the observable policy. As there is no single government responsible for the Euro and as a new monetary authority is responsible for the conduct of monetary policy, an international treaty had to define the rules of the game. The Maastricht Treaty was certainly strongly influenced by German convictions and fears. Germany, with a positive track record over decades in achieving relative price stability1 and as the only country with an internationally accepted currency, had most to lose in a monetary union and least to gain.2 The final outcome was however a questionable compromise. The Treaty’s most prominent pillars were the convergence criteria to delineate the conditions for admission to the Euro club. Only belatedly was it realized that satisfying the convergence criteria is not enough to have rules for the functioning of the EMU once members are in. So the Growth and Stability Pact completed what was overlooked. Many economists criticized from the beginning that the deficit and debt rules were arbitrary, that the rules on interest and inflation convergence were overlapping and that the exchange rate stability condition was toothless with the 15 % up and down corridors around the central parity introduced in 1993 to end the EMS upheavals. Seriously damaging is that the Treaty does not even consider how to deal with an economic crisis. The compromise did not allow for what is the fate of market economies, namely years of relative stability and occasional booms and busts. During the 2008/2009 financial crisis it, indeed, was desirable to let the automatic stabilizers play and to support through discretionary fiscal policies aggregate demand. Any limitations to the current budget deficit did not make compelling sense. Of course, countries that had already at the beginning of the crisis public debt levels in 1 Germany paid a price for sustained price stability: its growth performance was consistently lower than those of France or Italy since the 1960s. It is thus not clear that a German design of EMU was the best for all members – a point that becomes clearer in the present crisis. 2 Some people argue, like Mallaby (2011) and patrons of Greek or Italian taverns, that Germany was the big winner as it could sell its wares more easily in monetary union. On its own Germany would have had a revaluation like Switzerland and a lesser current account surplus. This is not economics and also ignores the fact that, for example, despite the revaluation of the Swiss franc the Swiss current account surplus represents 14 % of GDP in 2011. 2 excess of the 60 % limits, levels that were thus officially brand-marked by the Maastricht Treaty as excessive, ran into unchartered waters. The Treaty did not foresee rules for a crisis, nor a distribution of responsibilities in case of crisis. What are the responsibilities of deficit countries and of surplus countries? Can the European Central Bank (ECB) deviate from its normal conduct of affairs? In case of a serious crisis it should be acceptable to deviate from standard rules but how and by how much? Surely the worst case is not to foresee crisis management and to quarrel about it when the house is on fire. Would it not have been useful to specify rules for “exit”? Still worse, the Treaty suggests that countries have to deal responsibly with their own problems and in that they should obey market discipline. This is what one might read into the ”no-bail-out” clause. But it did not escape markets that the no-bail-out clause is firmly against European principles of mutual support and Community solidarity. For instance, in the Charter for the European Investment Bank, it is stated that all shareholders (all member of the EU) are solitarily liable for any losses of the EIB. Hence, what to think of the no- bail-out? Clearly, that when push comes to shove there will be assistance. Hence the clause was not credible like the rest of the Treaty. After all, right from the beginning, for political convenience, the rules were bent or simply ignored: Italy and Belgium, two founding countries of the EU, had up to twice the debt level specified as the limit in the Treaty but were admitted. This decision is highly comprehensible, but the collateral damage is severe: the credibility of the Treaty was already diminished right from the beginning. As markets did not pay attention to the no-bail-out clause, with hindsight rightly so, interest rates in all members countries converged to German levels. For many countries interest rates were low as never before. With inflation rates higher in the South3 than in the North, real interest rates were still lower and even negative in the South. This made borrowing exceptionally attractive, and households, firms and governments reacted 3 In this paper South means Greece, Italy, Spain, Portugal, Malta and Cyprus. Ireland is not part of it and France could be either way. 3 rationally. So, the over-borrowing in some countries can be seen as the consequence of a not credible no-bail-out. I used the term over-borrowing. For governments there is an easy way to measure over-borrowing: In excess and away from the Maastricht limits. But what about the private sector? What is bad about increasing borrowing from abroad if these funds are used for investment to increase productivity and over time to turn out products that can be sold abroad to pay back the debt? Nothing, in fact. But the point is that in all Southern borrowing countries, investment in plant and machinery did not increase, productivity sagged and all the borrowed money went into higher consumption and the real estate sector. The North financed a better life in the South. A nice illustration is provided by the cover page of The Economist, November 12th 18th 2011.4 The no-bail-out was in fact a helpless and desperate message to governments not to over-borrow. It was not a message to markets because European governments distrust markets5 and were happy to cheat on markets. Just imagine that European governments had trusted markets and attributed to markets a surveillance role by making it credibly clear that there is no bail out. That, therefore, risk premiums of a few percentage points are “normal” and perfectly acceptable for countries with high debts levels, weak governance and no business plans for stabilization. That could have been done by not tolerating during the first ten years of EMU debt levels near double the limit in the Treaty. Another way would have been to apply risk premiums to loans by EU institutions like the EIB. Any credible nobail-out would in all likelihood have moderated the indebtedness in those countries hardest hit by the current crisis. As the example of fiscally responsible Spain shows, fiscal irresponsibility is only one source of problems in the EMU. Another, of equal importance, is excessive foreign borrowing. It is even worse if a country suffers from both, over-borrowing by the government and over-borrowing from abroad. It is 4 Silvio Berlusconi, then prime minister of Italy, in vain used to calm markets by pointing to the fact that “restaurants across this happy country are always packed”. This is precisely the point. He should have completed the picture by referring to the capacity utilization of factories and to the investment rate. 5 Angela Merkel won much popular applause for her statement :”We must reestablish the primacy of politics over the markets” suggesting that markets caused the trouble and political leaders are the victims. 4 absolutely remarkable that the Treaty does not waste a line on foreign borrowing. The reason is probably that in a country with its own currency one never worries about the balance of payments of a particular province and such balances are not even calculated. But for a country it matters whether a large part of the current financing comes from sources abroad or not. Foreign lenders/investors may review their positions in light of the policies pursued (deficit increases?), the political changes (Berlusconi staying?) and the performance (drop in growth?) of a country. Not to deal with procedures for adjustment of sustained imbalances is a tremendous oversight that adds to the negative assessment of the Treaty. 3. The inconsistencies of the Euro The Euro is part of an effort to build a European Federation step-by-step, based on some fundamental (continental) European values. Those of concern are: First, the equality of all members independently of size, level of income and political maturity. Second, the goal of income convergence with the aim to establish nearly equal average incomes across the EU. This justifies policies such as the regional aid, the second largest item of expenditure of the EU Commission, and of the cohesion fund. Third, the (continental) EU embrace of the social market model, or mixed economy model with a sizeable welfare state. The role of markets is acknowledged, with some distaste and only accepted when difficult to avoid. The result is a highly regulated and in many cases overregulated economy with notable inefficiencies in labor markets. Fourth, the goal in EMU of price stability. Fifth, in EMU no constraints on balance of payments imbalances other than those delivered by the market. These various goals are incompatible and therefore some of them must go; otherwise EMU will never work well. I consider them under four analytical headings. a) EMU is not an Optimum Currency Area. Already before the establishment of EMU numerous academics, above all American economists (see, e.g., Dorn- busch, 1996), have warned that the EU is not an Optimum Currency Area (OCA). Faced with negative asymmetric shocks countries need to 5 adjust through real wage adjustments. These adjustments are typically easier with an exchange rate adjustment than within a currency union. The more rigid real wages are the less able is a country to adjust in a currency union. There is one alternative, at least for long-term adjustments, and that would be labor migration (or capital migration). Europe does not fare well with either adjustment mechanism. At least on the continent, wages are remarkably rigid and migration is costly with the language and institutional barriers of each country. These arguments were always pushed aside as a “theoretical” view and mobility and flexibility were considered to be endogenous, that is, currency union will lead to more flexibility and mobility.. The EU was seen by its proponents as a steadily converging set of countries, assisted by grants and cheap loans from Community sources. No serious attention was given to how to cope with asymmetric shocks, as demonstrated by the total absence of such considerations in the Treaty. b) How to regain lost competitiveness? Since the start of the Euro unit labor costs (ULC) have diverged dramatically. In Germany, they have increased by less than 10 %, in Greece by nearly 40 %, in Italy by more than 30 % before the correction began as a result of the market pressure during the crisis. That means that wages have increased by more than productivity in all countries but in the Southern countries by much more. As a result cost competitiveness of Southern countries has decreased dramatically. This is all the more a matter of concern, as the productive structure of these economies has little market power and is not at the forefront of the innovation frontier. It is difficult to see how countries in which currently unemployment trails around 20 % (Spain, Greece) and youth unemployment is dramatically higher, can generate the growth necessary to move closer to full employment. Particularly, as their labor markets are over-regulated and union power strong, a necessary general wage reduction of some 30 % is unlikely to be brought about. Equally unlikely is a jump in productivity given the ranking of these countries in international comparisons of attractiveness for investments. c) Adjustment to external imbalances is unstable. Unfortunately, the difficulties go even deeper. There is no need for an asymmetric shock to 6 upset the system. The goal of income convergence contributes to higher inflation rates in the catching-up countries by the Balassa-Samuelson argument. And, indeed, over the last 10 years one observes consistently higher inflation rates in the Southern deficit countries than in the Northern surplus countries. This implies that Southern countries had a real revaluation and Northern countries a real devaluation. Instead of redressing the imbalances, this unstable system created increasing imbalances. The system itself is sick, not (only) the individual operators. Whilst it is desirable to run current account deficits during a catching-up phase matched by the surpluses of the more developed countries it is not possible to run current account deficits forever nor is it desirable to run surpluses forever. Let’s suppose Germany (or the Netherlands) would (finally) realize that it should not run current account surpluses forever and rather invest a greater part of its national savings at home. For this a revaluation would be required. But Germany can neither influence the external value of the Euro which in all likelihood is pulled down by weaker member countries nor can it engineer an internal revaluation without giving up price stability.6 To produce an internal revaluation Germany would have to raise its inflation rate above the average in the Eurozone. This by itself may hurt the price stability sensitivity of Germans. Moreover, since most Southern members have had an inflation above the average such a German policy would not be compatible with price stability. Hence, countries , whether Southern or Northern, are trapped in clearly suboptimal, unstable equilibriums. To get out, Germany would have to accept the highest inflation rate in the Eurozone and, in all likelihood would have to give up cherished price stability. d) Economic structure does matter for monetary union. Before EMU, the question of whether the difference in structure of member countries matters for a well-functioning monetary union, was debated but in the end 6 The surplus countries are often criticized and seen as profiting from the South by running surpluses. This mercantilist fallacy fares well with politicians. My point is that surplus countries are prevented from achieving their desired external equilibrium both inside and outside the Euro area by the rules of the Euro. If , say, Germany was on its own its currency would have appreciated and its external surplus would have shrunk. This argument is often used to demonstrate that Germany would lose outside of the Euro, a popular fallacy, already evoked in footnote 2. 7 judged as being a matter of secondary importance. For one, if inflation is a monetary phenomenon then with a common monetary policy and a vertical Phillips curve there should not be problems. Also, the behavior of workers and unions faced with the greater transparency of competitive conditions in a common monetary area was expected to fall into line, renouncing their historic strategies. This was a touch too optimistic as the divergence in ULCs clearly shows. But differences in economic structure amount to more. According to the World Bank’s “Ease of Doing Business Survey” Italy ranks 87th (behind Albania) and in the Transparency International’s corruption index 67th. Greece is even worse: it ranks 100th (just behind Yemen) in the Ease of Doing Business ranking and 78th in the corruption index. This is in stark contrast to Northern Europe: Denmark, Finland, Sweden, and the Netherlands rank in the top 10 of the least corrupted public sectors and 6 Northern European countries are in the top 20 in the ranking according to Ease of Doing Business. These observations suggest that it was a mistake to ignore structural differences and that next time, when countries such as Rumania or Bulgaria are candidates, structure ought to be taken more seriously. The need for reforms is colossal and the pertinent question is: is a monetary union, anchored on price stability, with the objective to realize income convergence, and the side constraint of medium-term external equilibrium a really realistic proposition for countries with fundamentally different structures and levels of development?7 4. Crisis Management Germany has been much criticized for being slow and reluctant, and in the end, too harsh in managing this crisis. I think this view misses the point. First, it was and is extremely difficult to evaluate the costs and benefits of various policy actions. What was the probability of contagion of an early Greek debt restructuring? Would the cost be lower or higher compared to 7 Of course, for the present crisis management one cannot wait for changing the treaties which is one of the fundamental problems in this crisis. To advance money first and hope for rule changes later would require credible governments. 8 what was actually done? What would be the cost/benefit for the monetary union of a Greek exit? All one hears is “incalculable high”. What is the risk of France being attacked? What would be the cost or benefit for Germany to leave? All these questions are difficult to answer, catastrophic consequences cannot be assumed away ex ante, and therefore the most prudent approach is not to do anything extreme. Second, as pointed out by De Grauwe (2011),in a crisis fiscal management by any one country in the Eurozone is more difficult than for a country with its own currency, as monetary union creates a strong negative externality. An increase of the deficit raises uncertainty and bond investors will require a higher risk premium, thereby deteriorating further the debt situation. If a country operates its own currency, the currency will depreciate, thereby increasing cost competitiveness and the future capacity to pay back with the effect of diminishing fears. Importantly, the government with its own currency can always pay back its debt by monetization so the risk of default is apparently less.8 As an example it is useful to compare the UK with Spain: Spain has less debt, less of a deficit and pays much higher interest rates than the UK. However, this constraint on government deficit spending in EMU need not to be overvalued. The depreciation of the currency in a country with its own currency Competitiveness only improves competitiveness if the real exchange rate depreciates. That requires that the pass-through to domestic prices be limited. Moreover a devaluation of the currency is not helpful when the country has important debt in foreign currency. A country like the UK has the best of all worlds: it has a net creditor position and if it had debt it would be in domestic currency. The pound, by the way, did not depreciate, despite the vast fiscal turn-around. What in my view differentiates the UK and Spain more significantly is that the UK is a net international lender and Spain a massive net borrower. 8 Apparently, because monetization implies higher inflation rates so the real value of the debt repayment is decreased. Any way investors lose. 9 Third, the Treaty did not provide a method to deal with the crisis as argued above. All political leaders were therefore overwhelmed by the task, for lack of experience and lack of guidelines. How to deal with a crisis in a given country is already a formidable challenge for any government. How to deal with it in a club of 17 countries is infinitely more complex. Fourth, to decide by unanimity on a financial commitment in a club with very asymmetric preferences, where some countries are known receivers, others are known potential receivers and the remaining countries are known payers is very, very difficult. In such a context, where quick actions are required, where wallets need to be opened and in exchange not only tough but useful, workable measures need to be decided, there is an absolute need for leadership. Unfortunately, one of the great weaknesses of Europe in general and of EMU in particular is the lack of leadership. In fact, the admirable European idea of equality of all members, whether small or large, whether rich or poor, whether in deficit or in surplus negates and denies leadership. The historic cooperation between France and Germany to advance European matters was always seen with great suspicion by the others. EU members outside of the Euro area have felt offended by not having been fully consulted in the crisis management. Fifth, it needs to be noted that Germany has never aspired to take leadership in the EU. One reason is that it did not, and still does not, feel at ease in such a role, given its historic past. This reticence I think is the right attitude as illustrated by the frequent attacks on Merkel with extensive references to Nazi attitudes. Moreover, Germany seems to lack the skills required for leadership. In relation to EU commissioners like Jacques Delors or Mario Monti their German colleagues were discreet and unremembered. Germany could not even propose an acceptable candidate for the presidency of the EU when it was its turn. 10 Sixth, having accepted by constraint to act together with France as leader, Germany was criticized for the slowness of opening the wallet.9 As Germans had always feared that such a crisis would happen, and observed that some countries were parodies of seriousness, the population at large was not amused. The country with the smallest gain from monetary union was supposed to make the biggest financial effort for saving it. That, and the institutional constraints, made it difficult to find quicker financial solutions. But nevertheless, Germany has offered to pay up at the condition of corresponding changes of the rules. That makes sense, but in a crisis there is no time for treaty changes. Let me be clear, it needs to be recognized that the crisis management with tattering German leadership, not knowing what to do and whether it should assume leadership, was dismal. For much too long was the idea of a debt restructuring categorically rejected when it was clear to most that debt restructuring was unavoidable (see, e.g., Steinherr, March 2010). The late acceptance of restructuring was of course unnecessarily much more drastic. The IMF was initially not admitted to “mess around” with EMU internal matters, before the embarrassing insight gained ground that IMF expertise and resources, were needed. The funds made available with a reduced risk premium were still far too expensive for a country like Greece that was by a long shot unable to pay at any rate of interest. Having spent at the beginning of the crisis money on interest forgiveness would have saved a lot of trouble and a much higher bill now. The macro-economic policies imposed by the Troika were totally inadequate. It is known that the IMF would have preferred an approach with budget savings delayed and greater insistence on reforms to generate growth. As the variable of concern is (debt/nominal GDP) and the reduction in deficit financing produces in the short run (without a currency devaluation) a decline in GDP the focus on debt reduction was very 9 Here it should be noted that Germany is not any longer among the rich countries of Europe, ranking in 9th position in the EU in terms of per capita GDP. Other countries insisted on special guarantees for their financial involvement or argued that their per capita income was too low to pay up. 11 debatable.10 The counterargument is, of course, that had the Greek government/public sector been of greater trustworthiness, the delayed deficit reduction would have been more acceptable. At any rate, the unfortunate German obsession with debt certainly influenced the final policy choices. They make the same choices at home where they are equally debatable, but this does not help crisis countries. The prolonged illusion that the South faced liquidity problems due to vicious market forces, not realizing for too long that liquidity problems can quickly turn into solvency problems, and that at any rate Greece has a solvency and not a liquidity problem, resulted in another unnecessary and costly misjudgment. 5. What should be done? Given the present situation and the political difficulties with deep seated reforms such as the fiscal pact, it seem beneficial to think about all options and consider a comprehensive cost/benefit analysis for each and every country and for the EU as a whole. As it is generally assumed that Germany is the biggest beneficiary I start by examining this assumption. Is Germany the main beneficiary of the Euro? Particularly in the South it is argued that Germany (resp. the North of the Eurozone) is the main beneficiary of the Euro by running an export surplus with the South thereby sustaining jobs and growth in Germany and taking jobs away in the South. Even Chancellor Merkel and the media do not tire in asserting that the Euro brings Germany great advantages and that it is in the interest of Germany to defend the Euro. It is important to check the validity of these assertions. If it turned out that economically the Euro was not an important source of gain and, on the contrary, an economic burden, then it would be necessary to find alternative reasons for Germany to pay dearly to save the Euro. One such alternative reason would be the argument that the political gain for 10 With an income multiplier between 1 and 2, a deficit reduction by 5 % would result in a real GDP decline between 5 % and 10 %. 12 Germany outweighs the economic cost. By implication, the political cost for Germany of leaving the Euro would be very substantial. The political argument is hard to quantify. Suffice it to observe that the case is by no means clear. Germany never wished to act as a European leader precisely to avoid being criticized for dictating its will on member countries. Providing massive financial support without any say, however, is not a responsible way of managing the Euro. But changing the rules of the change to conform more to German convictions or influencing policy in crisis countries, possibly debatable austerity policies, is profoundly resented and leads to anti-German sentiments. Since Germany tries to act by influencing the policies of the European institutions there is even the risk that Europe and the whole European idea is losing its attractiveness. Not being part of European arrangements, such as the Euro, such as Schengen, such as a European social model is increasingly considered as fortunate in parts of Europe. It seems therefore doubtful if it helps Europe and if it helps Germany politically to remain in the Euro. The economic argument is easier to deal with. It is clear that a wellfunctioning monetary union provides gains. They were doubtlessly exaggerated by the EU but they are real. The gains arise in a static sense from saving the costs of currency conversion and the absence of exchange rate uncertainty, plus avoiding abrupt change in competitiveness from exchange rate movements. Exchange conversion costs are real but relatively small; exchange rate uncertainty is easily hedged; and the movements of real exchange rates have been as pronounced in the Eurozone as before. Therefore, there are gains in a static sense but too small to fight for the Euro. The dynamic gains would materialize from an increase in investment to generate more growth. Such an increase would potentially occur if the Eurozone provided more stability and allowed more trade to exploit economies of scale. As the real exchange rate stability did not materialize there is little reason to expect that investment and growth in the Eurozone gained significantly. Using IMF data, the investment rate in the Eurozone countries was two percentage points lower during 2000-2010 than during 13 1990-2000. The growth of GDP was slightly above 2 % during 1990-2000 and only close to 1.5 % during 2000-2010. Even during the years before the crisis the average growth was lower than 2 %. Hence the dynamic gains cannot be seen, even before the crisis. Hence, even without the crisis, the gain from the Euro is not obvious. Adding the cost of the crisis turns it into a negative-sum game. The case for maintaining it is therefore not compelling for any member country. Perhaps it is the case that some countries (Germany?) gained massively whilst others (the South?) lost to add up to a negative gain? The Euro brought stability and international acceptance to countries that were unable to domestically achieve that. The only country that had these advantages already with domestic currency was Germany and those countries that pegged to the D-mark. Therefore Germany did not gain in stability and international acceptance but the South did. Interest rated declined substantially in the South and made the financing of high public debt levels easier. Low nominal interest rates close to German levels and higher price inflation turned the real interest in the South negative and provided the incentives for over-borrowing. The gain was for the South although it was a treacherous gain that led to the crisis. What about the exports of the North to the South? It first may be useful to put the German current account surplus of 5.5% of GDP (in 2012) into perspective. The Netherlands have a surplus of 7.7%, outside the Eurozone Sweden has 6.7% and Switzerland 13.2%. Germany has surpluses in its trade with countries outside the Eurozone as well (growing at a higher rate than its surplus with the Eurozone) and it always had surpluses before German unification. During the nineties Unification pulled temporarily resources from foreign trade to rebuilding the East. The fact that since 2000 the current account surplus of Germany has been growing is not due to monetary union but is a return to trend. 14 Is a current account surplus a gain and a deficit a loss? This is an old mercantilist idea, fundamentally flawed. A current account surplus represents for a country the net investment abroad. If a country wants to receive on a net basis funds from abroad then it must run (there is no other way!) a current account deficit. Would any Southerner be ready to argue that it would have been preferable for the South to lend money to Germany rather than receiving money from Germany? And, has this lending been gainful to Germany? If Germany does not get its money back with interest then the answer is immediate: no. But even if Germany does get its money back it is not a gain for Germany. And the fault is not with the receivers but with German policy. A permanent surplus of the current account implies that out of national savings part of it is invested abroad rather than at home. For example, in 2011 the national savings rate of Germany was 23.7 %. Instead of investing all of it in Germany only 18 % was invested at home and 5.7 % (the current account surplus) was invested abroad. The individual investor only looks at his return on capital but an investment at home creates jobs, output and taxes in the future. If the South had invested these loans productively then Germany would have transferred jobs from the North to the South, not the other way round. Unfortunately the borrowings were consumed in higher incomes and real estate speculation. What can we see from the data? In the early 1990s the investment rate in Germany was around 25 %, falling to 22 % in 2000 and to 18 % in 2011. So the fall was even more pronounced than for the Eurozone. The growth rate of Germany during the 1990s was on average 2.25 %, falling to 1.25 during 2000-2007, before the crisis set in, and to roughly 0,05 % during 2007-2012. So German growth fell even more than in the Eurozone and was for all the years in the Eurozone miserable. The reason why the public considers Germany robust and strongly growing is that 2010 and 2011 were good years, but forgetting that in 2009 German output dropped dramatically. What would have happened if Germany had not joined the Euro? Would it be a poorer country now? The experience of countries like Sweden, 15 Denmark or Switzerland suggests otherwise. They all were able to maintain price stability, even more so than the Eurozone, and their growth performance was better than the Eurozone’s and Germany’s. The expected gains from a monetary union failed to materialize even before the crisis and turned into a massive loss operation since the outbreak of the crisis. The main loser from a poorly designed monetary union is Germany, partly because it failed to bring about a proper design and adequate membership. What should and could be done? There are three options: trying to stick together, encouraging weaker members to leave, or Germany leaving the Euro. A. Trying to stick together This is the currently attempted approach. It requires a crisis management between austerity and growth stimulation that is difficult to achieve, creates massive resentment, and suffers from an uncertain outcome. It also requires Germany to assume financial responsibility, not enthusiastically supported by the German population, and leadership which is not accepted by most partner governments and their populations. It also requires a redesign of monetary union which is virtually impossible to be successful. One reason is that the European set up is unable to do that job. Despite 30 years of preparation for monetary union the Maastricht Treaty was a totally inappropriate political compromise producing and ending in turmoil. The other, and not unrelated reason, is that the composition of the Eurozone membership is too heterogeneous. The Eurozone is very far from resembling an optimal currency area. The governance is dominated by countries that do need or may need support. 16 The Southern request for a fiscal union in form of either creating Eurobonds, a Eurozone treasury or an ECB financing that in the end would need to be backed by some fiscal authority is not a way to get out of the problem. The North would only dig itself deeper into the mud. A good warning is provided by Italy. Italy had the Lira, a central government and a fiscal union. Did that provide monetary stability? Did that provide convergence between the South and the North as a result of massive transfers for 50 years? Why would Europe be more successful, given national jealousies and the refusal of external interferences? Is the goal of future monetary union to resemble the North-South divide of Italy? Should it be the case that Germany with a per capita income that makes it a middle-income country in the EU (Germany ranks 9th in the EU by GDP/capita) take on the risks of that enterprise and be the ultimate payer? If Germany enters into guarantees for the debt of other countries it will put its AAA rating at stake. The worst that can happen to the Eurozone is that Germany over-burdens itself. Its downgrade will also be costly for other members as the value of the supposed ultimate payer is reduced. And would not be greeted gladly by the German population. The risk of that strategy is very high. Disillusionment in the South, bitterness in the North, haggling over transfers, laxity in reforming the institutions in the South, insistence on wrong policies from the North, the moral hazard problems from the assistance provided, emergence of nationalistic attitudes. Do we really want that? B. Inducing problem members to leave EMU is at any rate confronted with the problem that there will be no new members that would fit gainfully, like Denmark, Great Britain or Sweden. It may be reticent to say no to countries that do not fit and would increase the existing problems like Island, Bulgaria or Rumania. Even for countries like Rumania it might well be better not to join in order to retain more flexibility in managing the economy. Similarly, exit from the Euro would make crisis management easier for Greece. A well prepared exit plan, 17 unlike a dark night operation, will not create the epidemic repercussions on other countries that is feared by decision-makers. Greeks fearing the reintroduction of a national currency will not exit the Euro. They may exit their banks but that they have already done. The political problem is which countries should leave and the only strong case is Greece. However, if the EMU was started anew, and without political constraints, the optimal membership would obviously be smaller. An EMU without Greece and without the future entry of other problem countries would, however, only be marginally better than the present configuration. C. Germany leaving the Euro On the basis of the above arguments Germany might be better off outside the Euro. Symmetrically, the South might be better off without the North. Germany would obviously trade as before with the Eurozone but it would make a much bigger contribution to redressing the competitive positions. And, in all likelihood, will other Northern members join Germany and create a northern Euro. In EMU the South had higher inflation rates than the North, the real exchange rate of the South appreciated and the real exchange rate of the North depreciated. As a result the deficits of the South increased over time and the surpluses of the North increased. This was an instable equilibrium. Now the wages in the South are falling to contribute to redress the situation but the pain for the population is high and the fall in wages may not be enough. If Germany left the Euro its new currency would in all likelihood appreciate and the competitive position of the South would improve. The German current account surplus would fall, a fact that is desirable for Germany itself and the South. Appreciation would dampen the inflation in Germany and depreciation of the South would tend to increase inflation, which helps lowering the ratio debt to nominal income. 18 Would it be expensive to exit? Yes, but probably not more expensive than to stay. All the claims that Germany has accumulated in Euro will be the same with Germany in or out. They may be paid back or not. If the Southern Euro depreciates, Germany will be paid less in Northern Euro but it makes adjustment for the South easier. The probability of default may not increase with Germany out, as depreciation makes payment easier. Germany has a choice of not being paid or being paid in depreciated currency. It can choose between remaining in and accumulate unknown financial obligations or put an end to it. Which is better ? From a long run perspective Germany has to compare the present value of financial obligations over the infinite future with the high present cost of getting out. Nobody knows which is higher. But certainly remaining is a severe and increasing constraint and a permanent source of conflict. As in private partnerships divorce can be very costly but it buys peace and tranquility. 6. Conclusions I have argued that all the European goals (all members are equal – income convergence – price stability – external equilibrium) cannot be maintained in EMU and that “emergency” rules are required to be better prepared for the management of the next crisis. With hindsight, if we were to create EMU again it would certainly be safer and more gainful for both, those in and for those out, to limit membership in EMU more strictly. This would recognize that not all potential members are equal and that structural differences matter. Now, after 10 years of EMU, and in a fully blown up crisis it would be too costly to unbundle EMU membership. But in all likelihood will it be very difficult for the most crisis stricken countries to survive in EMU. The question of exit will need to be answered during the coming years and rules for exit should become part of a revised Treaty. The German idea of rewriting the rules is a necessary one, although the internal inconsistencies cannot be eliminated. The focus on more discipline 19 makes sense but will not get us far. A particularly bad idea is to bring deviating countries to the European Court of Justice and have them fined. If fines were to become an important discipline enforcer then the present deficit limits should be replaced by surplus requirements when close to potential output. A country could then be fined when it fails to reach the required minimum surplus. It is obviously easier to pay fines during good times than during bad times. Another solution is to accept permanent external imbalances and high unemployment levels, compensated within a transfer union. The United States are often cited, forgetting that the United States have a common political culture (even Texas!), and a much leaner welfare state. A transfer union in Europe would be politically unpalatable to the payers for the high cost and for dislike of how funds are being used in some member countries.11 Nor should the hopes about what is achievable be exaggerated. Italy has had a monetary and fiscal union stretching from North to South. Since the 1950s the North of Italy is paying for the South. These transfers maintain the consumption levels in the South but the gap in the productive structures has widened over time. A Europe modeled on Italy is not an attractive proposition. In the EU, a modest transfer union exists already and how transfers through the regional and social funds are being used is not an encouragement to go beyond. Nor is the idea of a European treasury, as appealing as it might be in theory, attractive in light of experience. Any fiscal system is a complex web of taxes, tax bases, and subsidies that are being decided by parliaments. Any partial transfer would not make any sense. Nor are national parliaments likely to give up their rights and the European Parliament has not shown to be up to the task. Some believe (e.g. Junkers and Tremonti, 2011) that Eurobonds will be the solution. If all government debt is replaced by Eurobonds this can work, but is expensive and the moral hazard problem sizeable. If it is partial, then the 11 Konrad and Zschäpitz (2011) have computed the cost of a transfer union based on 2007 data with the principle of compensating 50 % of the difference with regard to EU average tax revenues and arrive at an annual cost of 445 billion Euros, of which Germany would have to assume 74 billion. They conclude: ”It is hard to believe that Europe could survive the political antagonisms that would be created by transfers of this magnitude”. 20 cost is smaller but still important and the inefficiencies mounting. At any rate, the basic difficulty remains: in such a case there need to be strict and enforced rules. Surveyed and judged by whom? By the political representatives of 17 (or more) countries with vastly different national interests? With a majority of actual or potential net receivers? A respectable short-run measure is the ECB standing ready, in support of the Stabilization Fund, to buy up any amount of government debt to send a strong signal to markets and to take out any excess supply. As there Is no scope for sterilization this quantitative easing would end up as an increase in base money. This could well result in lower risk spreads and not in a dramatic increase in inflation. In all likelihood are banks not ready to lend more and hence their cash will end up in excess reserves as during the 2008 crisis. It is a sensible way to calm markets, at least for some time, and avoid a spillover into a banking crisis. But it is no solution for making the Eurozone more coherent, more trustworthy and better equipped for growth. The Bretton Woods system blew up when the United States failed to deliver stability and fell prey to the Triffin dilemma. The Euro risks the same fate, being anchored on Germany as became blatantly clear in this crisis. If Germany overburdens itself then the Euro will be at risk. Germany will become riskier12 and the Euro will lose attractiveness as an international currency. Funds leaving Italy would no longer flow to Germany but outside of the Eurozone with an impact on the exchange rate. Germany could end up seeing exit as a lower risk alternative. References: De Grauwe, P. (2011), Managing a Fragile Eurozone, CESifo Forum, Summer Dornbusch, R. (1996); Euro Fantasies : Common Currency as Panacea, Foreign Affairs, September/October Juncker, J.-C. and G. Tremonti (2010), E-bonds Would End the Crisis, Financial Times, 5 December 12 On 23 November 2011 Germany was unable to auction a Euro 6 billion 10 year federal government bond issue and had to accept a Euro 3.64 billion turnout. Admittedly it was tightly priced at 2 % but still source of widespread market declines. 21 Konrad, K.A. and H. Zschäpitz (2011), The Future of the Eurozone, CESifo Forum, Summer Mallaby, S. (2011), Germany is the real winner in a transfer union, Financial Times, 24 November Steinherr, A. (2010), Greece and the Euro: Some unpleasant Truths, The Globalist, 12 March 22
© Copyright 2024