Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 575–583 Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Journal of Banking & Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf A unique ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ in China: Theory and evidence Ming Guo a,⇑, Zhan Li b, Zhiyong Tu c a Shanghai Institute of Advanced Finance, Shanghai Jiaotong University, Shanghai, China Department of Economics, W.P. Carey School of Business, Arizona State University, USA c HSBC School of Business, Peking University, Shenzhen, China b a r t i c l e i n f o Article history: Received 6 July 2009 Accepted 3 September 2011 Available online 10 September 2011 JEL classification: G11 G12 a b s t r a c t Unique to the world, China adopts a ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, which prevents investors from selling stocks bought on the same day. We develop a dynamic price manipulation model to study the effects of the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’. Compared to the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’, which allows investors to buy and sell the same stocks during the same day, we show that the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ reduces the total trading volume and price volatility, and improves the trend chasers’ welfare when trend-chasing is strong. An empirical test using data on China’s B-share stock market supports the model’s theoretical predictions. Ó 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: T + 1 trading rule Trading volume Volatility Trend-chasing 1. Introduction The Chinese stock market opened in December 1990, with two separate sub-markets: an A-share market (for domestic investors) and a B-share market (for foreign investors). Initially, both adopted the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’, which allows an investor to sell stocks bought the same day. However, in January 1995, the China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) abandoned this ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’ for A-share stocks and replaced it with a ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ – a unique institutional arrangement found nowhere else in the world. The ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ requires an investor to sell only stocks he purchased at least one day prior, and forbids him from selling stocks bought the same day. In China’s official newspaper, Renmin Daily, the authority claimed that the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ would effectively prevent excessive speculative trading and thus would be in line with the interests of retail investors.1 In 2000, China’s B-share stock market abandoned the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’, and adopted the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ as well. Despite the longstanding arguments in favor of the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, few theoretical models and little empirical evidence have been provided to explain and analyze this unique trading arrangement. Our paper may be the first to explore the effects of the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ on the welfare of various investors, the stock prices, and volumes, from both theoretical and empirical perspectives. We develop a parsimonious trade-based price manipulation model in which there are three types of traders: a strategic trader, mechanical trend chasers, and competitive risk-averse liquidity providers. The risk-averse liquidity providers passively clear the market by taking orders submitted by the strategic trader and trend chasers. The strategic trader maximizes her expected utility by manipulating the stock prices to induce trend chasers to follow her trading, whereas the trend chasers follow a pre-specified trading rule.2 The stock price is affected by the strategic trader’s manipulation trades as well as by the trend chasers’ trend-following behavior. We show that, compared with the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’, adopting the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ effectively reduces the total trading volume, as well as price volatility, and improves the trend chasers’ welfare if trend-chasing is strong. We test the model’s predictions by comparing trading volume and stock price volatility before and after the implementation of ‘‘T + 1’’, using data from China’s B-share market. We also check the robustness of our test by examining different measures of stock volatility and by controlling the effect of the ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy, which was introduced about the same time as the introduction of the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’. The empirical results support our hypotheses. ⇑ Corresponding author. Tel.: +86 21 62932017; fax: +86 21 62933418. E-mail addresses: mguo@sjtu.edu.cn, mguo@saif.sjtu.edu.cn (M. Guo), zhan.li@ asu.edu (Z. Li), zytu@szpku.edu.cn (Z. Tu). 1 Due to the lack of rigorous regulation in the early 1990s, China’s stock market is dominated by speculative trading, as in most emerging markets. 0378-4266/$ - see front matter Ó 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2011.09.002 2 Trend-following behavior is common in emerging markets, see Gelos and Wei (2002) and Khwaja and Mian (2005). It is very common among retail investors in China as well. 576 M. Guo et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 575–583 Our paper is closely related to the literature on stock market manipulation. Allen and Gale (1992) classify stock market manipulation into three categories: action-based manipulation, information-based manipulation, and trade-based manipulation. Our theory falls into the trade-based manipulation category, in which a trader manipulates a stock simply by buying and selling, without taking any publicly-observable action to change the firm’s value, or releasing any information to affect the price. Hart (1977) shows, in a dynamic deterministic setting, that trade-based manipulation is profitable when the stationary equilibrium is unstable or demand functions are nonlinear. Jarrow (1992) extends Hart (1977) to a stochastic environment and shows that the manipulation can be profitable if there exists a ‘‘price momentum’’, or when the speculator can corner the market. In these papers, the demand functions are exogenously given and their frameworks are thus of partial equilibria.3 We take a general equilibrium approach here. In our paper, there exist risk-averse liquidity providers who clear the markets so that the demand function is endogenously determined. In addition, we assume there exist trend chasers, who follow an exogenously-given trading rule. The rule requires them to buy stocks when the price goes up and sell stocks when the price goes down. DeLong et al. (1990) classifies this type of trading as positive feedback trading. They cite various empirical evidence to support this assumption. Our model is similar to DeLong et al. (1990) in that we also assume the rational strategic trader can manipulate the positive feedback trader to make a profit. However, our paper differs from theirs in two aspects. First, our model assumes information symmetry among traders because we focus on the effects of the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’. In contrast, DeLong et al. (1990) assume information asymmetry among different types of traders, aiming primarily at manipulative behavior. Second, in their paper, the equilibrium price is obtained by directly specifying demand functions for passive traders, while in our model, the demand of the passive traders, or, riskaverse liquidity providers, is determined by their own utility maximization, following Subrahmanyam (1991). Several papers document empirical evidence of market manipulation for both emerging and developed markets. Using trade-level data from Pakistan stock market, Khwaja and Mian (2005) find that brokers earn at least 8% higher returns on their own trades through a specific trade-based ‘‘pump and dump’’ price manipulation scheme. Mei et al. (2004) empirically test a price manipulation pattern based on investors’ behavioral biases, using data on Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) prosecution of ‘‘pump and dump’’ manipulation cases. Aggarwal and Wu (2006) also provide empirical evidence from 142 litigation cases of stock price manipulation in the U.S. from 1990 to 2001. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 specifies the assumptions of the model. Section 3 solves the equilibrium for the case of the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’. Section 4 solves the equilibrium for the case of the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’. In Section 5, we compare the equilibrium features of these two cases with regard to trading volume, price volatility, and investors’ welfare. Section 6 tests for the predictions in Section 5, using data from China’s B-share market. Section 7 concludes the paper. 2. The model For tractability, we consider a two-day model in which there are three types of traders: a risk-averse strategic trader, trend chasers, and risk-averse liquidity providers. There are one risk-free bond and one risky stock available for trading. Without loss of generality, we assume that the interest rate for the bond is zero. Therefore, the bond’s price is always equal to 1. 3 See also Merrick et al. (2005) and Vitale (2000). The model involves two days, in which day 1 comprises periods 1–4, and the stock payoff is realized and the stock is liquidated in day 2.4 Before period 1, the strategic trader and the risk-averse liquidity providers know that the stock’s payoff is D0. Uncertainty about the stock’s payoff arises in period 1 and ends in the second day. From periods 1 to 4, the strategic trader and the risk-averse liquidity providers know only that the stock payoff D follows a normal distribution with a mean D0 and a variance r2. The uncertainty is resolved in day 2 and the stock payoff D is realized. The strategic trader chooses her optimal trading strategy, while trend chasers follow an exogenously-given rule. Risk-averse liquidity providers trade passively to provide immediacy to other investors for liquidity premium, and set equilibrium prices competitively based on the order flows submitted by the strategic trader and trend chasers.5 Note that because there is no information asymmetry, it does not make any difference to risk-averse liquidity providers whether they observe the order flows separately or in total. Since the liquidity providers are risk averse, the order flows submitted by the strategic trader and trend chasers affect the stock prices in equilibrium. As a result, the strategic trader chooses her optimal trading strategies by taking into account the impact of her trades on prices. The strategic trader has an exponential utility of the form exp (cW), where c is her risk-aversion coefficient. We also assume an exponential utility exp (cW) for risk-averse liquidity providers. Without loss of generality, we normalize the number of risk-averse liquidity providers to be 1. The stock price in period i is denoted by Pi, where i 2 {1, 2, 3, 4, 5}. Since there is no uncertainty in period 5 (day 2), the price in period 5 satisfies that P5 = D. Since there is no uncertainty before period 1, the stock price before period 1 is equal to D0. We assume that the strategic trader’s initial stock endowment is X0, where X0 is a positive constant. The initial endowments of risk-averse liquidity providers are assumed to be zero and their holding in period i, where i 2 {1, 2, 3, 4}, is denoted by Qi. For simplicity, we assume that the strategic trader trades in periods 1 and 3, and the quantities she trades are denoted by X and X, respectively. The trend chasers follow the strategic trader’s trading and trade in periods 2 and 4. The quantities chosen by them in these two periods are denoted by Y and Y, respectively. They are given by the following rule: Y ¼ gðP1 D0 Þ; ð1Þ and Y ¼ gðP3 P2 Þ; ð2Þ where g is a positive constant. As in DeLong et al. (1990), g represents the intensity of the bullishness of trend chasers. We now introduce the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ into the model. Under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, the quantities an investor sells in day 1 cannot be more than his initial position at the beginning of day 1. This rules out the case where an investor buys a large number of stocks and sells this quantity during the same day. 4 In essence, we only focus on the intra-day trading behaviors of the investors, to study the effect of the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’. However, our results should be robust in a more complicated setup. 5 It is worth noting that individual investors also provide liquidity in other markets, as empirical evidence has indicated. Kaniel et al. (2008, 2009) have shown that riskaverse individual investors provide liquidity to institutional investors in the U.S. Therefore, it is reasonable to assume that the risk-averse liquidity providers (individual investors) clear the market at the equilibrium price. Technically, many papers assume exogenous demand functions of risk-averse liquidity providers, for tractability reasons. For example, Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2005) incorporate the price impacts of order flows and downward-sloping demands of risk-averse liquidity providers into asset pricing models. In their paper, the demand curve is exogenously given. Our paper, on the other hand, endogenizes the demands of the liquidity providers when incorporating the price impacts of order flows. M. Guo et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 575–583 577 In this section, we solve for the equilibrium under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’. where X is the quantity she trades in period 3 and X0 is her initial position. Simple derivation yields the strategic trader’s budget constraint in period 3: 3.1. Equilibrium prices W 5 W 2 ¼ ðX 0 þ XÞðP5 P2 Þ þ XðP5 P3 Þ: Since the risk-averse liquidity providers’ goal is to clear the markets in each period, the sum of the positions of the strategic trader, trend chasers, and risk-averse liquidity providers must be equal to zero. We thus obtain Her maximization problem in period 3 is then given by6: 0 ¼ Q 1 þ X; s:t: ðaÞ W 5 W 2 ¼ ðX 0 þ XÞðP 5 P2 Þ þ XðP5 P3 Þ 3. Equilibrium under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ 0 ¼ Q 2 Q 1 þ Y; 0 ¼ Q 4 Q 3 þ Y: The risk-averse liquidity providers set prices competitively to clear the market. Following Subrahmanyam (1991), the quantities traded by risk-averse liquidity providers satisfy: 1 E½Q t ðD Pt Þ cVar½Q t ðD Pt Þ ¼ 0: 2 ð4Þ With the above equation, we establish the relationship between the equilibrium prices and the risk-averse liquidity providers’ holdings, in the following proposition. Proposition 1. The stock P t ¼ D0 12 cr2 Q t ; t ¼ f1; 2; 3; 4g. c max EðW 5 jF 3 Þ VarðW 5 jF 3 Þ 2 X price in period t is ð10Þ ðbÞ X P X 0 ; ð3Þ 0 ¼ Q 3 Q 2 þ X; ð9Þ where F 3 denotes her information set in period 3. Since her objective function is quadratic, we need only to solve the optimization problem in (10) without constraint (b) and then determine whether the solution is larger than X0. The optimization problem without constraint (b) is given by c max EðW 5 jF 3 Þ VarðW 5 jF 3 Þ 2 X ð11Þ s:t: ðaÞ W 5 W 2 ¼ ðX 0 þ XÞðP 5 P2 Þ þ XðP5 P3 Þ: Substituting (5), (1), and constraint (a) into the objective function in (11) yields: max W 2 kðX 0 þ XÞð1 þ gkÞX kXðX þ gkX þ XÞ kðX 0 þ X þ XÞ2 : X Proof. Since D N(D0, r2), substituting E[Qt(D Pt)] = Qt(D0 Pt) and 12 cVar½Q t ðD Pt Þ ¼ 12 cQ 2t r2 into (4) yields Pt ¼ D0 12 cr2 Q t ; t ¼ f1; 2; 3; 4g. h Define k ¼ 12 cr2 . Using equations (3) and Proposition 1, we obtain P1 ¼ D0 þ kX; P2 ¼ D0 þ kðX þ YÞ; P3 ¼ D0 þ kðX þ Y þ XÞ; ð5Þ P4 ¼ D0 þ kðX þ Y þ X þ YÞ: Substituting (5) into (1) and (2) yields the quantities traded by trend chasers in periods 2 and 4, which are given by Y ¼ gðP1 D0 Þ ¼ gkX ð6Þ and Y ¼ gðP3 P2 Þ ¼ gkX: ð7Þ 3.2. The strategic trader’s optimization problem In day 1 (periods 1–4), the strategic trader trades in periods 1 and 3 to maximize her expected utility in day 2 (period 5). We use the backward induction method to solve for her optimal trading strategies. We first solve the optimization problem of the strategic trader in period 3 and then solve for her optimal trading in period 1. 3.2.1. The maximization problem in period 3 In period 3, the strategic trader maximizes her expected utility in period 5 based on the information available in period 3. With the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, the quantity that the strategic trader sells cannot be more than X0. Therefore, we have the following constraint: X P X 0 ; ð8Þ ð12Þ The first-order condition (FOC) gives: 1 ðgk þ 3ÞX : X0 ¼ X0 2 4 ð13Þ It is easy to check that the second-order condition is negative. Thus, the solution (13) is the optimal one. If X 0 P X 0 , then (13) is also the solution to the constrained optimization problem given by (10). If X 0 < X 0 , because the objective function is quadratic and concave, the constraint will be binding at X0. Therefore, combining the above two cases, we can write the optimal solution to problem (10) as: X ¼ maxfX 0 ; X 0 g: ð14Þ Eq. (14) shows that the strategic trader’s optimal strategy in period 3 is a nonlinear function of her initial endowment X0 and her chosen quantity X in period 1. Eq. (13) shows that X 0 is negatively correlated with X. The implication is that the strategic trader tends to trade in the opposite directions in periods 1 and 3 to manipulate markets and obtain trading profit by inducing trend chasers to follow her transaction. An example is that she buys low and sells high. Note that X 0 is also negatively correlated with her initial endowment X0, because the risk-averse strategic trader tends to hold a position with a smaller magnitude to reduce the risk. In addition, Eq. (14) shows that the quantities she sells in period 3 are up-bounded, which is consistent with the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’. 3.2.2. The maximization problem in period 1 In period 1, the strategic trader’s budget constraint is given by W 5 W 0 ¼ X 0 ðP5 D0 Þ þ XðP5 P 1 Þ þ XðP 5 P3 Þ; ð15Þ and her optimization problem is: 6 Given u(W) = exp (cW), max E[u(W)] is equivalent to max EðWÞ 12 cVarðWÞ . 578 M. Guo et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 575–583 c jXj 6 kX 0 ; k > 0: max EðW 5 jF 1 Þ VarðW 5 jF 1 Þ X 2 s:t: ða0 Þ W 5 W 0 ¼ X 0 ðP5 D0 Þ þ XðP5 P1 Þ þ XðP5 P3 Þ 0 ðb Þ X P X 0 ; ð16Þ where F 1 is the strategic trader’s information set in period 1. Substituting constraint (a0 ), (1) and (5) into her objective function (16) yields: max X 2 X XðX þ gkX þ XÞ ðX 0 þ X þ XÞ 2 0 ð17Þ s:t: ðb Þ X P X 0 : Given X ¼ maxfX 0 ; X 0 g, we solve the optimization problem given in (17) by considering X 0 P X 0 and X 0 < X 0 , respectively. We summarize the results in the following proposition. Proposition 2. Under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, when gk > 1, the strategic trader has two optimal trading strategies. The first one is: X ¼ gk 4þ 1 X 0 and X ¼ X 0 . The second one is: X⁄ = X0 and X ¼ gk 4þ 1 X 0 . When 0 < gk < 1, the strategic trader has a unique optimal trading strategy, i.e., X ¼ X ¼ gk2Xþ0 7. Proof. See Appendix A. h Proposition 2 shows that the strategic trader’s optimal trading strategy depends crucially on gk, the strength of the trend-following behavior. The larger gk is, the more manipulation profit the strategic trader can obtain. When gk > 1, the profit from market manipulation dominates the inventory risk she takes, therefore the optimal trading in periods 1 and 3 shall go in opposite directions. Since the model structure is symmetric, buying in the first period and selling in the third one shall yield the same utility as selling in the first period and buying in the third one. However, when gk < 1, market manipulation profit is relatively low, so reducing the risk of stock-holding becomes the dominant consideration. Then the strategic trader tends to reduce her inventory in both periods 1 and 3. 4. Equilibrium under the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’ In a market adopting the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’, an investor can sell stocks she purchases during the same day. In this section, we solve for the strategic trader’s optimal strategies in this institutional arrangement. Compared with the previous section, the only difference is that she solves her maximization problem without the constraint X P X 0 . We solve the strategic trader’s optimal trading quantities X⁄ and X by backward induction, as in the previous section. In period 3, the strategic trader maximizes her expected utility in period 5, given the quantity X she trades in period 1. The solution is equal to X 0 , derived in the previous section, that is, 1 ðgk þ 3ÞX : X ¼ X0 2 4 ð18Þ The strategic trader’s maximization problem in period 1 is given by 1 1 1 1 X 0 gk X 0 X X 20 : max ðgk þ 7Þðgk 1ÞX 2 þ X 8 2 2 2 2 X0: gk þ 7 The above constraint means that the quantity the strategic trader buys or sells cannot be more than kX0 in the first period. It is a mechanical assumption to obtain an interior solution. We further assume that k P 1, and k can be understood as an investor’s funding ability.7 Comparing the utilities from X = kX0 and X = kX0, we find that the objective function (19) is maximized at the right boundary: X ¼ kX 0 : ð22Þ Substituting (22) into Eq. (18), the strategic trader’s optimal trading 0 quantity in period 3 is given by X ¼ 12 X 0 ðgkþ3ÞkX . We summarize 4 the above results in the following proposition. Proposition 3. Under the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’, when gk > 1, the strategic trader’s optimal trading quantities are: X⁄ = kX0 and 0 X ¼ 12 X 0 ðgkþ3ÞkX . When 0 < gk < 1, the strategic trader’s optimal 4 2 trading quantities are: X ¼ X ¼ gkþ7 X0. The interpretation of the optimal trading strategies in Proposition 3 is the same as in Proposition 2, except that the solution is unique when gk > 1. This is due to the fact that we impose a bound for the first-period trading under the ‘‘T + 0’’ scenario, which makes the model asymmetric. 5. Comparison of ‘‘T + 1’’ and ‘‘T + 0’’ trading rules In this section, we compare the equilibrium properties for these two trading mechanisms. First, in Table 1, we summarize the strategic trader’s optimal trading strategies, described in the previous two sections. Next, we compare the equilibrium properties, including total trading volumes, price volatilities, and investors’ welfare. 5.1. Equilibrium volumes We use V(T+1) and V(T+0) to denote total trading volumes under the ‘‘T + 1’’ and ‘‘T + 0’’ trading rules, respectively. Under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’: V ðTþ1Þ ¼ jX j þ jY j þ jX j þ jY j gk þ 1 gkðgk þ 1Þ X0 þ X 0 þ X 0 þ gkX 0 4 4 g 2 k2 þ 6gk þ 5 X0: ¼ 4 ¼ Under the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’: V ðTþ0Þ ¼ jX j þ jY j þ jX j þ jY j 1 ðgk þ 3ÞkX 0 X0 þ ¼ kX 0 þ gkkX 0 þ ðgk þ 1Þ 2 4 1 ¼ ðkðgk þ 7Þ þ 2Þðgk þ 1ÞX 0 : 4 Comparing V(T+1) with V(T+0) yields: 1 2 2 7 3 X0 : g k ðk 1Þ þ gkð2k 1Þ þ k 4 4 4 ð19Þ V ðTþ0Þ V ðTþ1Þ ¼ ð20Þ It is easy to note that when k > gkþ3 ; V Tþ0 V Tþ1 > 0. Since k P 1, gkþ7 adopting the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ tends to reduce the total trading volume. Intuitively, the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ imposes an upper-limit for the strategic trader to manipulate the price, thus inducing less trading. When gk < 1, the first-order condition yields X ¼ ð21Þ The second-order condition is 18 ðgk þ 7Þðgk 1Þ < 0. Substituting 2 (20) into (18), we obtain X ¼ gkþ7 X0 . When gk > 1, the objective function (19) is convex; it is maximized at either 1 or +1. In order to ensure a bounded solution, we make the following assumption: 7 This assumption is for tractability reasons. However, we think it is also reasonable, since an investor is likely to obtain a loan of the same dollar value, using her initial stock holding X0 as collateral. M. Guo et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 575–583 Table 1 The strategic trader’s optimal trading strategies under ‘‘T + 1’’ and ‘‘T + 0’’ trading rules. gk > 1 X ðg 2 k2 þ 2gk 7ÞX 20 8 kðgk 1Þðkgk þ 7k þ 4Þ 4 2 X0 8 1 ¼ ðgk 1Þðk þ 1Þðkgk þ 7k gk 3ÞX 20 : 8 U ðTþ1Þ U ðTþ0Þ ¼ 0 < gk < 1 ⁄ X T+1 gkþ1 4 X 0 ðor T+0 kX0 X0 Þ X 0 12 X 0 or gkþ1 4 X0 ðgkþ3ÞkX 0 4 X⁄ X 2 gkþ7 X0 2 gkþ7 X0 2 gkþ7 X0 2 gkþ7 X0 579 When k P 1, we have: U Tþ1 < U Tþ0 : 5.2. Price volatilities We use Pmax Pmin to measure the price volatility, where Pmax and Pmin are the maximum and minimum prices in day 1, respectively.8 Under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, the strategic trader has two equilibrium trading strategies. It is easy to check that these two strategies actually yield the same price volatility measured by Pmax Pmin. Without loss of generality, we consider only the case where gk > 1.9 Under this scenario, the price rises in periods 1 and 2 and falls in periods 3 and 4. The maximum price must be P2 and 2 the minimum price can be D0 or P4. We have P 2 ¼ D0 þ k ðgkþ1Þ X0 4 g 2 k2 2gk3 and P4 ¼ D0 þ k X . 0 4 When gk > 3, P4 > D0, min{D0, P4} = D0, rðTþ1Þ ðgk þ 1Þ2 ¼ jP2 D0 j ¼ k X0 : 4 When gk < 3, we have P4 < D0, min{D0, P4} = P4, rðTþ1Þ ¼ jP2 P4 j ¼ kX 0 ð1 þ gkÞ: Under the ‘‘T +0 trading rule’’, P2 ¼ D0 þ kðgk þ 1ÞkX 0 ; P 4 ¼ D0 þ k 12 þ 1gk k ð1 þ gkÞX 0 < D0 , so the price volatility is: 4 rðTþ0Þ 1 1 gk k ð1 þ gkÞX 0 ¼ jP2 P4 j ¼ kðgk þ 1ÞkX 0 k þ 2 4 1 gk þ 3 þ k ð1 þ gkÞX 0 : ¼k 2 4 Simple calculation yields that: when gk > 3, 1 4 rðTþ0Þ rðTþ1Þ ¼ kðgk þ 1Þðkgk gk þ 3k þ 1ÞÞX 0 > 0; and, when gk < 3, 1 4 rðTþ0Þ rðTþ1Þ ¼ kðgk þ 1Þðkgk 2 þ 3kÞX 0 > 0: Therefore, we find that the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ reduces the price volatility relative to the ‘‘T + 0’’ rule when the strength of trend-following is strong. 5.3. Welfare In this section, we compare both the strategic trader and trend chasers’ welfare under two trading rules. Given the results presented in Tables 1 and A.1 in Appendix A, it is easy to see that when 0 < gk < 1 the strategic trader’s expected utilities under the two scenarios are the same. We next consider the case that gk > 1, where 8 The volatility measurement with high price minus low price has been widely used by financial professionals. It is also explored in the academic literature, e.g., Garman and Klass (1980). 9 When gk < 1, these two mechanisms have the same price volatility, based on Table 1. Thus the strategic trader is better off under the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’ when k P 1. Intuitively, the strategic trader can manipulate prices to a larger extent without constraints on the maximum quantities she can sell. With regard to trend chasers, we measure their welfare by their expected trading profit. Under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, the trend chasers’ welfare is given by: ðgk þ 1Þgk X 0 þ ðP4 D0 ÞgkX 0 4 ðgk þ 1Þ2 ðgk þ 1Þgk g 2 k2 2gk 3 ¼ k X0 þ k X 0 gkX 0 X0 4 4 4 1 ¼ gkð1 þ gkÞðg 2 k2 2gk þ 13ÞkX 20 : 16 W ðTþ1Þ ¼ EðD P2 Þ Under the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’, the trend chasers’ welfare is given by: 1 ðgk þ 3ÞkX 0 W ðTþ0Þ ¼ ðD0 P2 ÞgkkX 0 þ ðP 4 D0 Þ X 0 þ gk 2 4 1 2 2 2 ¼ gk2 ð1 þ gkÞðg 2 k2 k þ 4kgk þ 2gkk þ 4k þ 13k þ 4ÞX 20 : 16 The difference between trend chasers’ welfare under the ‘‘T + 1’’ and ‘‘T + 0’’ mechanisms is given by: 1 2 2 k gX 0 ðk þ 1Þð1 þ gkÞðg 2 k2 k g 2 k2 16 þ 2kgk þ 2gk þ 13k 9Þ < 0: W ðTþ0Þ W ðTþ1Þ ¼ This shows that trend chasers are better off under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’. In summary, we show that compared with the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’, adopting the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ reduces the total trading volume and the price volatility, and protects the welfare of trend chasers. Intuitively, the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ imposes an upper-bound on the magnitude to which the strategic trader can manipulate prices. As a result, total trading volume, as well as price volatility, decreases and trend chasers benefit from a smaller amount of negative profit from trading under ‘‘T + 1’’. The results are summarized in the following proposition. Proposition 4. Compared with the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’, the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ leads to smaller total trading volume, lower price volatility, and higher welfare for trend chasers. 6. Empirical test In this section, we test the model’s predictions that, when trend-chasing is strong, introducing the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ will reduce both price volatility and total trading volume. In China’s stock market, price manipulation and trend-chasing behavior are very common. Therefore, we expect that the above hypothesis holds. The Chinese stock market is separated into an A-share market and a B-share market. In the A-share market, listed stocks are traded in Chinese currency RMB, while all stock transactions listed in the B-share market are carried out in foreign currencies. The Ashare market was introduced in December, 1990 and included only eight stocks. The B-share market was introduced in February 1992. 580 M. Guo et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 575–583 Initially, both markets adopted the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’. In January 1995, however, the A-share market abandoned the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’ and replaced it with the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’. The B-share market adopted the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ in December 2001. We test the predictions in Proposition 4 with data from the B-share market. We understand that we can obtain richer data from the A-share market, but that market switched its trading rule at a time when the Chinese stock market was still quite immature and we are concerned with the quality of the data, so we believe that using data from the B-share market could be the better choice. For comparison, we include two years of data before and after the switch from the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’ to the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, to test our hypotheses. More specifically, our sample consists of daily data of 109 B-share stocks listed on China’s B-share market from December 1999 to November 2003. There are 955 trading days included: 479 trading days are under the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’ and 476 trading days are under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’. We use i to denote the stock, i 2 [1, 109], and t to denote the trading day, t 2 [1,955]. Let Vi,t denote the daily volume of stocki in the number P of shares at day t. Following our theory, we use ln Pi;t;h as a meai;t;l sure of daily price volatility of stock i in day t, where Pi,t,h and Pi,t,l are the highest and lowest prices of stock i on day t, respectively. Under the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’, the average daily trading volume and price volatility for stock i are given by: V ðTþ0Þi ¼ 479 1 X V i;t and 479 t¼1 rhighlow ¼ ðTþ0Þi 479 1 X rhighlow ; 479 t¼1 i;t where rhighlow is stock i’s volatility on day t, which denotes volatili;t ity calculated from Pi,t,h and Pi,t,l. Similarly, under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, the average daily trading volume and price volatility for stock i are: V ðTþ1Þi ¼ 955 1 X V i;t and 476 t¼480 rhighlow ¼ ðTþ1Þi 955 1 X rhighlow : 476 t¼480 i;t For robustness, we also use the standard deviation of close-toclose log return series for each stock, to measure the stock’s volaP close;t tility. The return series r i;t ¼ ln P close;t1 , where Pclose,t and Pclose,t1 are stock i’s close prices on day t and day t 1, respectively. The volatility under the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’ is defined by the sample stanqffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi ffi P479 1 2 dard deviation of the return series: rstd t¼1 ðr i;t r i Þ , ðTþ0Þi ¼ 4791 where ri is the average of the return series. The volatility under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ can be defined in a similar way and we denote it as rstd ðTþ1Þi . Denote the differences in trading volume and price volatilities due to the change of trading rule by DV i ¼ ¼ rhighlow rhighlow V ðTþ0Þi V ðTþ1Þi ; Drhighlow i ðTþ0Þi ðTþ1Þi and Drstd ¼ i std rstd ðTþ0Þi rðTþ1Þi respectively. Table 2 presents the summary statistics of DV i ; Drhighlow and Drstd for 109 B-share stocks. i i Table 2 Summary statistics of 109 B-share stocks’ DV i ; Drhighlow and Drstd i . i DVi/shares Drhigh—low i Drstd i Mean Std. dev. Skewness Kurtosis 1,076,723 1,062,113 0.6487 6.2444 0.0171 0.0038 0.4847 3.8327 0.0130 0.0093 7.0493 67.7707 Min 5% Qntl. 25% Qntl. 50% Qntl. 75% Qntl. 95% Qntl. Max 2,701,784 111,190 462,714 871,991 1,521,220 3,224,088 5,254,964 0.0045 0.0105 0.0146 0.0177 0.0194 0.0222 0.0268 0.0732 0.0065 0.0108 0.0108 0.0165 0.0186 0.0381 Table 2 shows that the average volume as well as price volatility before the change in the trading rule are higher than those after the implementation of the trading rule. To better understand the difference, we plot the differences of volumes and volatilities under the ‘‘T + 0’’ and ‘‘T + 1’’ trading rules for the 109 B-share stocks in Fig. 1. The upper graph is the difference of volumes under the ‘‘T + 0’’ and ’’T + 1’’ trading rules. The middle graph is the difference of volatilities measured by maximum and minimum price differences. The lower graph is the difference of volatilities measured by the standard deviation of the return series. It is easy to see that most stocks have lower average daily volumes under ‘‘T + 1’’ than under ‘‘T + 0’’, and almost all stocks’ average volatilities are lower under ‘‘T + 1’’ for both measures. We conduct the Wilcoxon Signed Rank test of our hypotheses.10 The null hypothesis is that there is zero difference in trading volumes (and volatilities) due to the change of the trading rule, and the alternative hypothesis is that the difference is greater than 0. The results, summarized in Table 3, show that the differences in trading volume and volatilities are significantly greater than 0. However, another important policy change occurred in 2001 as well. This policy allows domestic investors to invest in the B-share market after February 19, 2001. This ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy attracted more investors, hence more capital into the market. As the trading volume and volatilities in the stock market are also affected by the number of investors, it would be premature to conclude it is the switch from ‘‘T + 0’’ to ‘‘T + 1’’ that caused the reduction of average trading volume and volatilities. We check the robustness of our test by taking into consideration the effect of the ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy, using two approaches. First, it is worth noting that the ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy is introduced earlier than the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’. Therefore, if we use only the sample data after the implementation of the ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy to conduct the Wilcoxon Signed Rank test for trading volume and price volatilities, then our results are not driven by the ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy. There are two stages in the B-share market’s ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy. From February 19, 2001 to June 1, 2001, domestic investors were only allowed to use deposits made to domestic commercial banks before February 19. After June 1, domestic investors were allowed to trade B-shares with deposits made to domestic commercial banks after February 19, as well as with foreign funds transferred from overseas. To account for the potentially different impacts of these two stages, we construct two samples in our empirical estimation: February 19, 2001 to September 25, 2002, with 195 trading days before and after the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, respectively, denoted as ‘‘Sample 1’’, and a shorter sample period starting from June 1, 2001 to June 20, 2002 with 126 trading days before and after the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, respectively, denoted as ‘‘Sample 2’’. We calculate the differences in trading volume and price volatilities as before. Because we use the data sampled after February 19, the date the ’’Opening-up’’ policy began, the differences of trading volume and price volatilities before and after ‘‘T + 1’’ exclude the effect of the ’’Opening-up’’ policy, leaving only the effect of the change in the trading rule. We conduct the Wilcoxon Signed Rank test of our hypotheses. The null hypothesis is that there is zero difference in trading volumes (and volatilities) due to the change of trading rule, and the alternative hypothesis is that the difference is greater than 0. The results, summarized in Table 4, show both differences are still significantly greater than 0. The second approach for checking the robustness is to separate the effect of the ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy and the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’, using two-year sample period data. Since the introduction of the 10 Wilcoxon Signed Rank test is a nonparametric test, commonly used to compare two sample medians without the assumption of the distribution. 581 M. Guo et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 575–583 Denote V Tþ1=Tþ0 ¼ ln VV Tþ1 . We further decompose VT+1/T+0 into Tþ0 the part which can be explained by the change in the trading rule and explained by the increase in the number of shareholders, Tþ1 NSTþ1=Tþ0 ¼ NS , which is a proxy variable for the ‘‘Opening-up’’ NSTþ0 policy. This decomposition is in line with the spirit of our above empirical analysis and separates the effects of the change of trading rule and the ’’Opening-up’’ policy. Following this logic, we conduct the following regression: V Tþ1=Tþ0 ¼ a þ bNSTþ1=Tþ0 : ð23Þ V Tþ1 , V Tþ0 Note that VT+1/T+0 is the logarithm of thus if we can reject the null hypothesis of ‘‘H0:a P 0’’, then we can conclude that volume under the ’’T + 1 trading rule’’ is smaller. Thus the constant a measures the effect of the change from ‘‘T + 0’’ to ‘‘T + 1’’ and b measures the effect of the ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy. Similarly, we define ! highlow Tþ1=Tþ0 r ! rhighlow rstd Tþ1 and rstd : ¼ ln Tþ1 Tþ1=Tþ0 ¼ ln highlow rstd rTþ0 Tþ0 We have the following two regressions: rhighlow Tþ1=Tþ0 ¼ a þ bNSTþ1=Tþ0 ; rstd Tþ1=Tþ0 ¼ a þ bNSTþ1=Tþ0 : Fig. 1. Differences of volumes and volatilities under ‘‘T + 0’’ and ‘‘T + 1’’ Trading Rules, 1999–2003. ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy changes the number of investors participating in the B-share market, we use the number of shareholders to capture the effects of the ’’Opening-up’’ policy. From the Wind Financial Database, we find the data regarding each B-share’s number of shareholders for each year during our sample period from December 1999 to November 2003. Denote NST+0 as the average number of shareholders under the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’ from December 1999 to November 2001 and NST+1as the average number of shareholders under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ from December 2001 to November Tþ1 2003. We define NSTþ1=Tþ0 ¼ NS , which measures the increase of NSTþ0 shareholders from ‘‘T + 0’’ to ‘‘T + 1’’. We summarize the descriptive statistics for NST+0 and NST+1 in Table 5. ð24Þ ð25Þ To further check the robustness, we also carry out our regression for different time horizons. We estimate our models using samples within one-year and two-year observations, before and after the switching of trading rules, respectively. We present the results in Table 6. Table 6 shows that the constant terms are significant at the 5% significance level. A one-sided t-test can reject the null hypothesis of ‘‘H0: a P 0’’ at the 5% significance level. Thus we can confirm that volumes and volatilities are all smaller under the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ than under the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’ after controlling for the effect of the ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy. It is worth noting that in Table 6, the coefficient of NST+1/T+0 is negative but not significantly different from zero. This coefficient measures the contribution of the ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy to volume and volatility, which is driven by two offsetting effects. On the one hand, the ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy brings more rational investors to the B-share market. Competition among rational investors makes intentional manipulation less effective. As a result, the trading volume and price volatility tend to decrease. The reduction in trading volume and volatility is consistent with the argument that more rational speculators stabilize asset prices, which dates back to Friedman (1953).11 Tirole (1982) also shows that price bubbles rely on the myopia of traders and that they disappear if traders are all rational. On the other hand, the ’’Opening-up’’ policy introduces more irrational trend chasers to the B-share market as well, which leads to stronger trend-chasing (a larger g). As shown in Sections 5.1 and 5.2, both trading volume and price volatility are positively related to g. Hence, volume and volatility tend to increase. Our empirical results indicate that in China’s B-share market, these two effects roughly offset each other, though the first effect is weakly stronger than the second one. As the coefficient is not significantly different from zero, this negative coefficient should not be overly emphasized. 7. Conclusion China’s stock market adopts a unique ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’: an investor is only allowed to sell stocks he bought at least one day prior, and is forbidden to sell stocks he bought during the same day. In this paper, we develop a dynamic price manipulation model to analyze the effects of the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ in terms of trading 11 See also Shleifer and Vishny (1997). 582 M. Guo et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 575–583 Table 3 Results of Wilcoxon Signed Rank test. Sample periods Price volatility (rhigh–low) Trading volume (V) Test statistics P-value Price volatility (rstd) 1 year 2 years 1 year 2 years 1 year 2 years 8.84 2.2e16 8.42 2.2e16 9.06 2.2e16 7.85 2.2e15 8.83 2.2e16 8.83 2.2e16 Table 4 Results of test for the sample after ‘‘Opening-up’’ policy. Sample periods Price volatility (rhigh–low) Trading volume (V) Test statistics P-value Price volatility (rstd) Sample 1 Sample 2 Sample 1 Sample 2 Sample 1 Sample 2 8.26 2.2e16 8.88 2.2e16 8.71 2.2e16 9.06 2.2e16 7.98 2.2e15 8.81 2.2e16 Table 5 Summary statistics for NST+0 and NST+1. Sample periods Standard deviation Min Max Average number of shareholders under ‘‘T + 0’’ 2 years 4.67e+4 1 year 5.09e+4 Mean 4.65e+4 4.95e+4 4.88e+3 5.13e+3 2.61e+5 2.69e+5 Average number of shareholders under ‘‘T + 1’’ 2 years 5.67e+4 1 year 5.77e+4 4.78e+4 4.90e+4 1.06e+4 1.01e+4 2.65e+5 2.73e+5 Mathur (editor). Any remaining errors are our own. This project is supported by the HFRI. Table 6 Estimation results.a Coefficients 2 years 1 year 0.6566⁄⁄ 0.2810 0.0512 1.1131⁄⁄ 0.2540 0.0260 0.4378⁄⁄ 0.0404 0.0194 0.3149⁄⁄ 0.0730 0.0206 0.4589⁄⁄ 0.0275 0.0031 0.3672⁄ 0.0594 0.0095 Regression (23) a b R2 Regression (24) a b R2 Regression (25) a b R2 a We have tested our models for heteroskedasticity by using White test at the 10% level of significance. In regression (23), we find the evidence of heteroskedasticity during the 2-year sample period. For volatilities, we find that there is no heteroskedasticity in regression (24) and there is heteroskedasticity in regression (25) during both sample periods. For the cases when there is heteroskedasticity, we use the HC3 estimator (Huber, 1967 and White, 1980) for efficient estimation of coefficients’ covariance matrix. For all of the models under both sample periods, we can reject the null hypothesis of ‘‘H0: a P 0’’ at the 5% level of significance by a onesided t-test. ⁄ 5% Level of significance. ⁄⁄ 1% Level of significance. volume, price volatility, and investors’ welfare. We compare it with the usual ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’ adopted by all other equity markets, with respect to the above three aspects. We show that the ‘‘T + 1 trading rule’’ can effectively reduce the total trading volume and price volatility, and improves the trend chasers’ welfare compared with the ‘‘T + 0 trading rule’’, when the strength of trend-chasing is strong. An empirical test with data from China’s B-share market strongly supports our theory. Appendix A. Proof of Proposition 2 Step 1. We first consider the case where X 0 P X 0 . In this case, we have a boundary solution, i.e., X ¼ maxfX 0 ; X 0 g ¼ X 0 . Since X 0 X 0 ¼ 12 X 0 þ ðgkþ3ÞX P 0, we thus have 4 XP 2 X0: gk þ 3 Substituting X ¼ X 0 into (17) yields: max 2X 2 þ ðgk þ 1ÞX 0 X X 20 X 0 ð26Þ ðb Þ X P X 0 : The first-order condition gives: X0 ¼ gk þ 1 X0: 4 ð27Þ Similar to the period 3 problem, we have the period 1 solun o 2 tion X ¼ max X 0 ; gkþ3 X0 . We then solve the case where X 0 6 X 0 . In this case, we obtain: 1 ðgk þ 3ÞX : X ¼ maxfX 0 ; X 0 g ¼ X 0 ¼ X 0 2 4 ð28Þ Plugging Eq. (28) into (17) yields: 1 1 1 ðgk þ 7Þðgk 1ÞX 2 þ ðgk 1ÞX 0 X X 20 8 2 2 ðb Þ X P X 0 : max X 0 ð29Þ Acknowledgements We thank Qingying He, Minsoo Lee, Mike Pollinger and an anonymous referee for helpful comments. We also thank Ike The first-order condition gives: X¼ 2 X0; gk þ 7 ð30Þ 583 M. Guo et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 575–583 Whether (30) is optimal depends on the sign of the secondorder derivative, i.e., the sign of SOC ¼ 18 ðgk þ 7Þðgk 1Þ. Plugging Eq. (28) into X 0 6 X 0 yields: 1 ðgk þ 3ÞX 6 0: X 0 X 0 ¼ X 0 þ 2 4 2 X0: gk þ 3 ð31Þ For the case where X 0 6 X 0 , we also need to consider two subcases as well. The first subcase is gk < 1. Since SOC < 0, the object function (29) is quadratic and concave. Because 2 2 X 0 6 gkþ7 X 0 6 gkþ3 X0 , the optimal solution is 2 X ¼ gkþ7 X 0 . For the second subcase where gk P 1, the object function is quadratic and convex. Thus, it is maximized 2 2 at either X0 or ðgkþ3Þ X 0 . Plugging X0 or ðgkþ3Þ X 0 into Eq. (29) shows that X⁄ = X0 is the optimal solution. Therefore, we can summarize the above results obtained in Step 1 in the following lemma. n o 2 0 Lemma 1. If X 0 P X 0 , then X ¼ max gkþ1 4 X 0 ; gkþ3 X 0 ; if X 0 < X 2 and gk < 1, then X ¼ gkþ7 X 0 ; if X 0 < X 0 and gk > 1, then X⁄ = X0. Step 2. Lemma 1 gives only intermediate results for the strategic trader’s optimal trading strategy. We next obtain the equilibrium results by comparing the expected utility of wealth for the strategic trader in the cases of X 0 < X 0 and X 0 P X 0 . Simple calculation leads to the following summary table. Table A.1 presents the strategic trader’s optimal trading quantities in periods 1 and 3 and the corresponding expected utilities in two cases. From this table, it is easy to derive the final equilibrium trading strategy for the strategic trader. When gk > 1, the expected utilities for the cases X 0 > X 0 and X 0 P X 0 are the same. Therefore, the optimal trading quantity of the strategic trader in period 0 1 is not unique. It is given by either X ¼ ðgkþ1ÞX or X⁄ = X0. Cor4 respondingly, her optimal trading quantity in period 3 is given by 0 either X ¼ X 0 or X ¼ ðgkþ1ÞX . When 0 < gk < 1, comparing the 4 expected utilities between the two cases yields: ðgk þ 3ÞX 20 ðg 2 k2 þ 2gk 11ÞX 20 ð1 gkÞð5 þ gkÞ2 ¼2 > 0: 2 gk þ 7 ðgk þ 3Þ ðgk þ 7Þðgk þ 3Þ2 Therefore, the strategic trader’s optimal trading quantities in periods 1 and 3 are given by: X ¼ X ¼ 2X 0 : gk þ 7 X 0 P X 0 X Rearrangement gives: X6 Table A.1 The strategic trader’s optimal trading quantities and utilities. ⁄ X 0 < X 0 X EU1 X⁄ X EU1 ðg 2 k2 þ2gk7ÞX 20 8 ðg 2 k2 þ2gk11ÞX 20 ðgkþ3Þ2 X0 ðgkþ1ÞX 0 4 2X 0 gkþ7 2X 0 gkþ7 ðg 2 k2 þ2gk7ÞX 20 8 ðgkþ3ÞX 20 gkþ7 gk > 1 ðgkþ1ÞX 0 4 X0 0 < gk < 1 2X 0 gkþ3 X0 Note: EU1 is the expected utility in period 1. References Aggarwal, R.K., Wu, G., 2006. Stock market manipulation. Journal of Business 79, 1915–1953. Allen, F., Gale, D., 1992. Stock-price manipulation. Review of Financial Studies 5, 503–529. Brunnermeier, M., Pedersen, L., 2005. Predatory trading. Journal of Finance 60, 1825–1863. DeLong, J.B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L.J., Waldmann, R.J., 1990. Positive feedback investment strategies and destabilizing rational speculation. Journal of Finance 45, 379–395. Friedman, M., 1953. The case for flexible exchange rates. In: Friedman, M. (Ed.), Essays in Positive Economics. University of Chicago Press. Garman, M., Klass, M., 1980. On the estimation of security price volatilities from historical data. Journal of Business 63, 67–78. Gelos, G.R., Wei, S., 2002. Transparency and international portfolio holdings. Working Paper, IMF. Hart, O., 1977. On the profitability of speculation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 101, 579–597. Huber, P.J., 1967. The behavior of maximum likelihood estimates under nonstandard conditions. In: Proceeding of the Fifth Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, vol. 1, pp. 221–233. Jarrow, R.A., 1992. Market manipulation, bubbles, corners, and short squeezes. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 27, 311–336. Kaniel, R., Saar, G., Titman, S., 2008. Individual investor trading and stock returns. Journal of Finance 63, 272–310. Kaniel, R., Liu, S., Saar, G., Titman, S., 2009. Individual investor trading and return patterns around earnings announcements. Working Paper, CEPR. Khwaja, A.I., Mian, A., 2005. Unchecked intermediaries: price manipulation in an emerging stock market. Journal of Financial Economics 78, 203–241. Mei, J., Wu, G., Zhou, C., 2004. Behavior based manipulation: theory and prosecution evidence. Working Paper, New York University. Merrick, J.J., Naik, N.Y., Yadav, P.K., 2005. Strategic trading behavior and price distortion in a manipulated market: anatomy of a squeeze. Journal of Financial Economics 77, 171–218. Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1997. The limits of arbitrage. Journal of Finance 61, 35–55. Subrahmanyam, A., 1991. Risk aversion, market liquidity, and price efficiency. Review of Financial Studies 4, 417–441. Tirole, J., 1982. On the possibility of speculation under rational expectations. Econometrica 50, 1163–1181. Vitale, P., 2000. Speculative noise trading and manipulation in the foreign exchange market. Journal of International Money and Finance 19, 689–712. White, H., 1980. A heteroskedastic-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test of heteroskedasticity. Econometrica 48, 817–838.
© Copyright 2024